Long run apartment price dynamics in Swedish and German cities

Sviatlana Engerstam (Division of Real Estate Economics and Finance, Department of Real Estate and Construction Management, KTH Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm, Sweden)

Journal of European Real Estate Research

ISSN: 1753-9269

Article publication date: 10 August 2021

Issue publication date: 20 October 2021

1087

Abstract

Purpose

This study examines the long term effects of macroeconomic fundamentals on apartment price dynamics in major metropolitan areas in Sweden and Germany.

Design/methodology/approach

The main approach is panel cointegration analysis that allows to overcome certain data restrictions such as spatial heterogeneity, cross-sectional dependence, and non-stationary, but cointegrated data. The Swedish dataset includes three cities over a period of 23 years, while the German dataset includes seven cities for 29 years. Analysis of apartment price dynamics include population, disposable income, mortgage interest rate, and apartment stock as underlying macroeconomic variables in the model.

Findings

The empirical results indicate that apartment prices react more strongly on changes in fundamental factors in major Swedish cities than in German ones despite quite similar development of these macroeconomic variables in the long run in both countries. On one hand, overreactions in apartment price dynamics might be considered as the evidence of the price bubble building in Sweden. On the other hand, these two countries differ in institutional arrangements of the housing markets, and these differences might contribute to the size of apartment price elasticities from changes in fundamentals. These arrangements include various banking sector policies, such as mortgage financing and valuation approaches, as well as different government regulations of the housing market as, for example, rent control.

Originality/value

In distinction to the previous studies carried out on Swedish and German data for single-family houses, this study focuses on the apartment segment of the market and examines apartment price elasticities from a long term perspective. In addition, the results from this study highlight the differences between the two countries at the city level in an integrated long run equilibrium framework.

Keywords

Citation

Engerstam, S. (2021), "Long run apartment price dynamics in Swedish and German cities", Journal of European Real Estate Research, Vol. 14 No. 3, pp. 309-330. https://doi.org/10.1108/JERER-03-2020-0020

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2021, Sviatlana Engerstam

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

House prices have been rising in many countries since the 1990s (Figure A1 in Appendix 1). In some European countries such as, for example, Sweden and Norway, the price growth was so extreme, that it raised debates about emerging speculative bubbles (Asal, 2019). At the same time, this dynamics were not evident for all European countries. For example, in Germany and Portugal, real house prices have been stagnating over the last few decades (Figure A1 in Appendix 1). The real house price growth in Sweden during 1995–2018 was plus 216 percent or 9.4 percent per year, while in Germany, it was only 18.6 percent for the same period or one percent per year (Source: Eurostat, Author's calculations).

On the one hand, such high and persistent growth in house prices makes it an attractive investment that outperforms the traditional investments in stocks and bonds even if taking into account the lower liquidity of this type of asset. On the other hand, high house price growth in comparison with slow income growth occurring in the low-interest-rate environment makes housing less affordable with time. One more consequence of this process is that high house price growth might be an indicator of a potential bubble formation (Lind, 2009), and thus, it might cause risks for the stability of the financial system. For example, one might suspect a potential price bubble formation in cooperative apartments segment in Sweden, because it looks more volatile in the long run in comparison with single family house price dynamics (Figure A2 in Appendix 1).

Although the main factors that contribute to housing price growth in different countries at macroeconomic level are well examined [1], one question remains: What are the factors that prevent housing prices from persistently rising in the long run? If one of the goals of central bank policy is to maintain stability in the financial system, which in turn is closely connected to the housing market, then the focus should be on the relatively stable housing markets and factors that contribute to this.

Intention of this study is to analyze housing price dynamics from this new perspective and to correct this probably conceptual misunderstanding. It might be achieved by making a comparative analysis of two rather similar but contrasting countries – one with stable price dynamics such as, for example, Germany and the other one with the persistent price growth that has been observed in Sweden over recent decades. To the author's best knowledge this kind of analysis has not been conducted before and the results from it might help to understand long run property market dynamics in a better way. In line with this intention, the main research question of this study is:

RQ1.

Can changes in fundamental factors explain the difference in long run apartment price dynamics in Germany and Sweden?

As the major housing stock is generally concentrated in larger urban agglomerations, it is worth making such a comparative analysis on the regional level, like metropolitan areas. The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 contains a brief literature review of studies focused on housing price determinants in different countries. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 presents the methodological approach and panel cointegration technique for non-stationary panel data used to estimate the long run equilibrium relationship between apartment prices and macroeconomic fundamentals. Section 5 provides the empirical results of the model implementation. Finally, Section 6 contains conclusions and policy implications.

2. Brief literature review on macroeconomic determinants of housing prices

Empirical literature provides extensive evidence regarding various factors that affect housing price dynamics. The primary body of research is quite large and consists of more than three hundred thousand different studies that analyze factors affecting housing prices [2]. Most of the studies on housing price dynamics focused on the USA, UK, and a few other countries, primarily OECD members [3].

Only a selected number of studies are presented below to highlight the essence of the extensive research in this area. The selection of studies was made to match the following criteria: (1) Studies within housing economics area of reseach, (2) Studies are published in scientific journals, and (2) Studies cover developed countries in Europe and the USA. Some of these studies were done on an aggregated country level, others on a regional level, and in some cases, they cover both levels. These studies provide a base for the development of a methodological approach and a model in this paper.

Ozanne and Thibodeau (1983) were one of the first who attempt to discover the determinants of house prices in the USA, but their regression results were not significant. Other studies on more extensive data have found interconnections between different fundamental economic factors and house price dynamics. Particularly, Reichert (1990) has found that population, employment, mortgage rate, permanent income and construction costs affect the house prices at a national and regional level, and the impact of these variables differ between different regions. Poterba (1991) concluded that changes in real income and real construction costs are important explanatory factors of the cross-city pattern of house price appreciation. Abraham and Hendershott (1996) have found that the growth in real income and real construction costs and changes in the real after-tax interest rate, employment growth, income growth and real interest rate have an impact on house price changes. Baffoe-Bonnie (1998) demonstrated that housing prices are influenced by economic fundamentals such as mortgage rates, consumer price index, changes in employment and money supply. Jones and Hyclak (1999) also confirmed that unemployment and size of the labour force affect house prices. Jud and Winkler (2002) have found that real housing price appreciation is strongly influenced by the growth of population and real changes in income, construction costs and interest rates, as well as growth in housing wealth. A recent study carried out by Oikarinen et al. (2018) explores spatial heterogeneity in house price dynamics and discuss the role of price elasticity of housing supply as well as income elasticity of prices.

Giussani and Hadjimatheou (1992) were one of the first to develop an econometric model for house prices in the UK. They suggested that the number of households, personal disposable income per capita, house building costs and the total housing stock are the driving forces behind increases in house prices in the long run. Their results also suggest that fiscal and monetary policy have a direct impact on house prices, both in the short and the long run, through changes in personal disposable income, interest rates, and tax allowance on mortgage interest payments. Muellbauer and Murphy (1994) have found that the main determinants of the regional deviation in house prices from the UK average are income, rate of return, index of financial liberalization, mortgage interest rate, mortgage stock/income ratio, rate of acceleration of unemployment and regional population. Xu and Tang (2014) concluded that construction cost, credit, GDP, interest rate, and unemployment rate have a positive impact on house prices, while disposable income and money supply are negatively correlated with house prices. White (2015) confirmed the existence of a cointegrating relationship between Greater London real house price movements and income, gross mortgage lending and interest rates. A recent study carried out by Sivitanides (2018) provide evidence of a strong long run relationship between London house prices and key macroeconomic variables, such as UK GDP, London population and housing completions.

Studies done on an international level demonstrate a similar effect from fundamentals in comparison with studies done in the USA and UK. For example, Englund and Ioannides (1997) confirmed that GDP growth and real interest rate are strongly significant, but demographics do not appear to matter at all. Terrones and Otrok (2004) postulate that the growth rate of real house prices is explained by the past growth rates of real house prices, housing affordability ratio, real income growth, interest rates, the growth rate of real credit, population growth and a bank crisis dummy. The empirical results of Adams and Füss's (2010) study indicate that house prices are affected by construction costs and long term interest rates. Caldera Sánchez and Johansson (2011) concluded that the housing stock tends to have a positive and significant effect on prices in the long run, while the effect of declining interest rates is modest or small.

It is interesting to note that while some of the authors argue that fundamental factors affect housing prices (McCarthy and Peach (2004), Himmelberg et al. (2005), Hwang and Quigley (2006), Cameron et al. (2006)), others point out that the impact of these factors can be different depending on the data period, the underlying econometric model specifications, affordability indicators and asset pricing approaches (Case and Shiller (1990, 2003), Girouard et al. (2006), Mikhed and Zemčik (2009), Kundan Kishor and Marfatia (2017)). In addition, some of the factors might have stronger effects, while other low or no effect at all (Quigley (1999), Capozza et al. (2004), Gallin (2006), Miles and Pillonca (2008), Taltavull de La Paz and White (2012)).

Studies done after the Global financial crisis add other factors to the analysis. For example, Wheaton and Nechayev (2008) point out that second home and speculative buying, as well as the emergence of the risk-priced sub-prime mortgage market, are new and unique factors in the housing market in comparison with previous research in this area. Duca et al. (2011) found that credit standards for first-time homebuyers are important determinants of house prices, along with income, real user costs and the housing stock.

In summary, a majority of the literature in housing economics considers factors that might affect house prices both from the demand and the supply side. On the demand side, the typical factors are household income, interest rates on mortgage loans, different demographics, and labour market factors such as population and employment growth. Construction costs and housing stock developments often represent the supply side. The variety of factors that affect house prices are often called “fundamentals.” Another group of factors that are different from fundamentals includes expectations and behavior of the market participants, financing conditions, mortgage valuation policies, etc.

3. Data

3.1 Selection of the study objects

The three Swedish and seven German cities were selected for comparative analysis in this study. For various historical, geographical, social, economical and other reasons, the housing market in Germany and Sweden is heterogeneous and diverse in terms of price and types of housing. The largest metropolitan areas in Sweden are Stockholm, Gothenburg, and Malmö.

The biggest German metropolitan areas are often called the “Big 7”. They are Berlin, Hamburg, Munich, Cologne, Frankfurt, Stuttgart, Düsseldorf. Because houses in the eastern states of Germany do not meet modern standards of construction, they were not considered comparable for this study, and therefore they excluded from the analysis below (i.e. Berlin). Bremen is added to analysis to make German dataset more comparable with Swedish dataset on city level.

The size of the housing cooperative apartment segment in the total housing stock varies between 24–41 percent in Swedish cities and between 26–45 percent in Germany (Figures A3 and A4 in Appendix 2). The apartment segment represents quite significant and, in some cases, even a major part of the total housing stock in large metropolitan areas, therefore the analysis in this study has a main focus on it.

3.2 Data description

The dataset consists of 2 cross-section panels: 3 major cities in Sweden of 23 periods each (year 1996–2018) and 7 major cities in Germany of 29 periods each (years 1990–2018). The dataset is unbalanced with some missing values for certain variables either at the beginning or at the end of the dataset. All economic variables expressed in real terms. In contrast to all other variables like population and income that are different on the city level, the mortgage interest rate is common for all cities in each country. Data sources and detailed descriptions are presented in Table A1 (Appendix 3). Tables 1 and 2 provide descriptive statistics for Swedish and German cities data [4]. Later, all variables used in econometric estimations transformed into natural logarithm form mainly for the purpose of comparative analysis.

4. The methodology and the model

4.1 The methodological approach

This study applies DiPasquale and Wheaton (1992) theoretical framework for the long run equilibrium model of supply and demand in the housing market. It also applies Adams and Füss's (2010) approach and Pedroni's (2004) econometric methodology with some smaller modifications explained below. One principal difference is that analysis is done at a cross-city panel level in distinction to Adams and Füss's (2010) study, where the analysis was done on cross-country panel level. City level is more homogeneous compared to country level because countries might differ in socio-economic and legal environments, while cities of the same country do not [5]. Therefore, the comparative analysis of two countries based on two cross-city panels seems to be more appropriate in this setting.

For Sweden, the majority of studies were done on house price data for single-family houses which is available for an extended period (Asal (2018, 2019), Berg (2002), Claussen (2013), Hort (1998), Turner (1997), Wilhelmsson (2008), Yang et al. (2010)).

Turner's (1997) analysis focus on transaction prices for cooperative dwellings in Sweden during 1980–1993. He concluded that prices were affected by change in macroeconomic factors, credit deregulation and credit constraints. Hort (1998) applied the restricted error-correction model for real house price changes in 20 urban areas in Sweden in 1967–1994. Her findings confirmed that movements in income, user costs and construction costs had significant impact on real house prices. Berg (2002) argued that after tax real interest rates, stock prices and industrial production were important factors for real house price change in Stockolm region.

Wilhelmsson (2008) investigated the relationship between house prices and income in various regions in Sweden by using a panel data set of over 281 municipalities in 1991–2005. He found that income and employment have positive effect on price to income ratio, while vacancy rates, income tax and mortgage rates affected it in opposite way. Yang et al. (2010) measured the impact of interest rate shocks on regional house prices in Sweden in 1991–2002. They have found significant differences in monetary policy effects at regional level in Sweden. Claussen (2013) came to the conclusion that growth of house prices in Sweden in 1986–2011 might be explained by the development of household real disposable income, after tax real mortgage rate and household real financial wealth.

One of the recent studies done by Asal (2018) demonstates that growth of real house prices in Sweden in 1986–2016 was affected by growth in mortgage credit, real after-tax mortgage interest rates, disposable income and the real effective exchange rate. Asal (2019) study suggest that Swedish real house prices have been overvalued since the mid-2000s and that undervaluation of the real exchange rate partially explains the recent buildup of the housing bubble.

Apartment prices data in Sweden covers slightly more than about two decades, which is a rather short period, if observations are taken annually. To overcome this restriction, it is worth following the methodology applied in Adams and Füss (2010) and applying the panel cointegration approach proposed by Pedroni (1999, 2004). This approach allows us to use the T observations of time series of a single city as well as to pool the observable data over all cities N so that the effect of NT real observations is available for analysis. The advantage of this method is that: (1) it provides robust estimations due to larger sample asymptotics; (2) it estimates the country result at aggregated level by weighting the individual cities estimations; and (3) it presents differences among cities' elasticities, which allows us to analyze the level of cross-city integration. In addition, Adams and Füss (2010) point out that the panel data variables on house prices and their fundamentals are often cointegrated even when there is no cointegration between them in individual time series (Adams and Füss, 2010, p. 38).

Previous research done on German data includes, for example, studies done by Dust and Maening (2007), Koetter and Poghosyan (2010) that analyze single-family house prices at a regional level and include shorter time series such as one year or a decade. The study carried out by Kajuth et al. (2013) differentiates between single-family houses and apartments and point to significant effects of the housing stock per capita, income per capita, unemployment, population density, and growth expectations on house prices. They conclude that apartments in German cities show significant overvaluation of between 5 and 7 percent in the years 2011 and 2012, while single-family houses do not. Belke and Keil (2018) demonstrated that supply-side factors such as construction activity and housing stock as well as the demand side factors in the form of apartment rents, market size, age structure, local infrastructure and rental prices are robustly linked to fundamental real estate prices and thus can be used to detect misalignments of market prices.

In distinction to the previous Swedish and German studies presented above and which are mainly based on data for single-family houses, this study focuses on the apartment segment of the market and examines apartment price elasticities from a long term perspective. In addition, the results from this study highlight the differences between the two countries at the city level in an integrated long run equilibrium framework.

4.2 Macroeconomic fundamentals of apartment prices in the long run

In line with DiPasquale and Wheaton (1992) model and the literature review presented in Section 2, the following variables were chosen for analysis as macroeconomic fundamentals of apartment prices in the long run:

  1. Disposable income: According to DiPasquale and Wheaton (1992), an increase in economic activity leads to an increase in demand for space, D. This shifts the demand curve to the right and leads to an increase in rents, R, which increases house prices, P. According to Adams and Füss (2010), the widely used indicator of economic activity is disposable income, I. Therefore, the long run price elasticity of income is determined as follows:

(1)PI+=PD+DI+
  1. Mortgage interest rate: An increase in the mortgage interest rate affects the demand for houses negatively. A higher mortgage interest rate, r, lead to lower demand, which in turn decrease construction, C, and thus translates to lower housing stock, S. Lower housing stock increases rents, R, and house prices, P. Therefore, the long run price elasticity to mortgage interest rate is determined as follows:

(2)Pr=PS+SCCDDr
  1. Housing stock and construction: An increase in construction leads to the higher housing stock in the long run and vice versa. Higher housing stock lead to lower house prices keeping all other variables unchanged. Thus, the long run elasticity of prices to construction is determined as:

(3)PC+/=PSSC+

The minus sign of the effect of the construction and housing supply on house prices depends on the size of the construction in relation to the shift in demand. If overbuilding occurs, the effect of construction and thus increase in the supply of housing will be negative, while if the opposite situation takes place. i.e. when the size of the construction corresponds to the shift in demand or is less than that, the effect on prices will be either zero or positive [6].

  1. Population: Many studies found insignificant or even adverse effects of population growth, H, on house prices (Mankiw and Weil (1989), Hort (1998), Poterba (1991)). Nevertheless, this study considers it because population growth is one of the driving factors behind rapid urbanization and increasing housing demand in the cities. An increase in population might happen through natural demographic growth like baby boom periods, as well as high immigration from outside of the country and natural urbanization processes when people move to the cities from rural areas. Adding this variable to the equation of house prices might also help to avoid omitted variable bias. An increase in population lead to higher demand for space, D, thus leading to an increase in house prices, P. The price elasticity of population growth is determined as follows:

(4)PH+=PD+DH+
  1. Unemployment rate: Higher unemployment, U, is usually observed over periods with low economic activity and, therefore, considered as a factor that leads to a decrease in demand for housing. Moreover, considering the unemployment rate as a part of the equation for house prices might help to capture the effect of the changes in the employment rate of the labour force that is part of the population. Thus, the price elasticity of the change in unemployment rate is determined as follows:

(5)PU=PDDU

4.3 The long run model of supply and demand

In line with DiPasquale and Wheaton (1992) model the demand function is given as

(6)Dt=α+βxtD+δztD+et,
where xtD is a vector of macroeconomic variables affecting demand. Vector ztD captures city-specific factors affecting the housing demand at the micro-level, such as location, social environment, mortgage market characteristics, and taxation regulations. For estimation of the macroeconomic impact on the house prices the vector ztD should be incorporated into the error term, et, and Eq. (6) will be written as
(7)Dt=αβ1Pt+β2Ht+β3Itβ4rtβ5Ut+e˜t.

In Eq. (7) higher house prices Pt have a negative impact on demand (unless it is not a speculative demand), while higher income or population growth has a positive effect on demand. Higher mortgage rate and unemployment rate are expected to have negative effect on demand for housing.

In a similar way housing supply is given by

(8)St=η+γxtS+λztS+νt.

According to Colwell (2002), the long run supply of houses is directly connected to the construction of new houses and the depreciation levels of housing stock. Housing construction depends on house price level and construction costs. Construction costs include a wide range of cost items, including building materials and transportation, as well as labour costs. It is reasonable to assume that the construction costs level is not very diverse among different housing developers due to competition in the construction industry. Thus, change in construction costs affect long run housing supply through construction level in the short run.

One more component that affects the long run supply of houses is the depreciation rate. Since the maintenance level and overall housing standard is quite high in Sweden and Germany, we can assume that the depreciation rate is close to zero and to ignore the effect depreciation has on housing supply. Therefore, in line with DiPasquale and Wheaton (1992) and Colwell (2002), the long run housing supply equals to initial housing stock plus aggregated housing construction over the long term minus depreciation of housing stock. With an assumption of zero depreciation rate, the long run housing supply equals to total aggregated housing construction or total housing stock constructed over the long term.

Thus, the supply equation is expressed as

(9)St=η+γ1Pt+γ2St+ν˜t,
which incorporates micro factors such as the availability of land, governmental building provisions, construction costs level and depreciation of housing into the error term, ν˜t. In Eq. (9) higher house prices act as an incentive for housing developers to increase the supply of houses. Given that supply equals demand in equilibrium relationship, and then solving for house prices and considering panel structure, the final equation for house price will be
(10)Pit=αiγ2iSit+β2i Hit+β3iIitβ4iritβ5iUit+eit,
with
αi=αiηiγ1i+β1i,γ2i=γ2iγ1i+β1i=PiSi,β2i=β2iγ1i+β1i=PiHi,β3i=β3iγ1i+β1i=PiIi,
β4i=β4iγ1i+β1i=Piri,β5i=β5iγ1i+β1i=PiUi,and eit=e˜it ν˜it.

According to the theoretical model outlined above the expected sign for γ2i, β4i, β5i is negative, and for β2i and β3i is positive.

The econometric approach in this study is to apply the cointegration analysis for non-stationary panel data. The panel data combines information on the variation of the city data with information over time. The analysis is done on two levels: (1) The variables are tested for stationarity using panel unit root tests; (2) The long run equilibrium relationships are estimated though panel cointegration tests.

4.4 Panel unit root tests

Im et al. (2003) proposed the unit root test that allows for heterogeneous autoregressive roots known as the IPS test. Results of IPS stationarity tests for the Swedish and German datasets are presented in Tables 3 and 4. As it comes from the p-values from the IPS test the null hypothesis could not be rejected for all variables. Taking first differences revials stationarity in the panel setting so that all variables are considered as I(1) and thus suitable for cointegration test procedure.

4.5 Panel cointegration test

The Pedroni (2000) test for cointegration is applicable to heterogeneous panel with multiple regressors. This test also allows for unbalanced panels to be tested. Pedroni (2000, 2004) demonstrates that under general requirements the test statistics follow a normal distribution as T and N grow large and that the group and panel ADF statistics have the best power properties when T < 100, with the panel v and group p-statistics performing comparatively worse.

Table 5 presents Pedroni (1999) test statistics for the Swedish dataset. A group ADF test statistic of −1.672 for the Pedroni (1999) test rejects the null hypothesis of no cointegration at a 5 percent significance level. Thus, apartment prices in Sweden are cointegrated with apartment stock, population, disposable income, mortgage interest rate, and unemployment.

Table 6 presents Pedroni (1999) test statistics for the German dataset. A test statistic of −2.086 for the Pedroni (1999) test rejects the null hypothesis of no cointegration at a 5 percent significance level. Thus, apartment prices in Germany are cointegrated with apartment stock, population, disposable income, mortgage interest rate, and unemployment.

4.6 Cointegration-vector estimates

The single equation cointegration vector estimator proposed by Engle and Grander (1987) provides consistent estimations when the sample size T is large, but the statistical properties might be different for a smaller sample size. Inder (1993) and Stock and Watson (1993) demonstrate with macroeconomic time series data that results might produce quite poor estimations when the number of observations is not large.

The Panel Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares (DOLS) estimator introduced by Saikkonen (1991), Phillips and Moon (1999), and Pedroni (2000) augments the conventional OLS estimator by taking serial correlation and endogeneity of the regressors into account. In a series of Monte-Carlo simulations Kao and Chiang (2000) and Mark and Sul (2003) test the small sample performance of the panel DOLS estimator and provide evidence that it, in general, outperforms single-equation estimation techniques.

Keeping in mind restrictions that are valid for the dataset used in this study the main goal is to obtain the coefficient vector estimate γ of

(11)yit=ai+γxit+uit,
with the regressors xit being integrated of order 1:  xit=xit1+vit. In Eq. (11) yit is the apartment price of a city i and time t and xit is a 5x1 vector of apartment stock, population, disposable income, mortgage interest rate, and unemployment rate of city i and time t respectively. Correlation of the additional error component vit with uit is a potential source of bias and an effective protection from this bias is to explicitly control for this relationship by regressing uit on p leads and lags of vit,
(12)uit=s=p+pδisvits+uit=s=p+pδisΔxits+uit=δiszit+uit,
where the second equality follows from xit=xit1+vit and the third equality is simply a vectorized notation to conserve space [8]. Inserting this expression into (11) yields the endogeneity and serial-correlation adjusted regression:
(13)yit=ai+γxit+δizit+uit
from which the coefficient vector βDOLS=(γ, δi, , δN)  can be obtained.

The interpretation of the DOLS estimator is similar to a conventional panel OLS estimator except in one important respect: A fixed-effect estimator would show the response of apartment prices at a time t or generally at a time tp. The DOLS estimator shows the long run effects, which capture the accumulation of effects over time, as well as the stickiness of apartment prices. Thus, if all variables are in natural logarithms, the elements of the coefficient vector γ=(γ1i,γ2i,γ3i) demonstrates the average long term percentage in the regressor.

5. Empirical results

Table 7 demonstrates the estimation results for each city in Sweden as well as for the whole panel at the country level. In the latter case, the coefficients were obtained by averaging the individual city coefficients. Therefore, we can interpret the panel group coefficients as a group country's results.

Population and disposable income have a positive impact. Thus, a one percent increase in population leads to an 8.8 percent increase in apartment prices, and a one percent increase in disposable income leads to a 2.6 percent increase in apartment prices. This estimation of income elasticity of prices for apartments is higher than approximately one present elasticity found by Hort (1998), Claussen (2013) and Asal (2018) for single-family house prices in Sweden, and when compared to results of this study for the German dataset, which indicate that a one percent increase in disposable income leads to an almost one percent increase in apartment prices in German cities. As Terrones and Otrok (2004) note, real income growth per capita increases households' purchasing power and borrowing capacity, which, together with lower interest rates, increases households' capacity to borrow and drives house prices up.

Despite the expected negative impact on apartment prices from the supply side, apartment stock estimate has a positive sign–a one percent increase in apartment stock leads to a, on average, 3.7 percent increase in apartment prices in Swedish cities. Meen (2002) argues that if the housing supply is perfectly inelastic, the increase in demand will be choked off by higher prices. At the other extreme, if supply is fully elastic, the output will increase to the point at which prices are unchanged and therefore, higher supply elasticities induce lower long run income elasticities of house prices. Moreover, the ratio of house prices to income in the long run not only is determined by the direct estimate of the coefficient on income in the house price equation but is a systems property depending also on the effect of the housing stock on prices and the price elasticity of new housing supply (Meen (2002), p. 12). Housing supply in Sweden is not considered as perfectly elastic due to regulations that exist in the rental sector, and this leads to the process that demand for apartments in housing cooperatives is continually growing despite persistent growth in prices, which in turn perfectly corresponds to the supply side response over the long term.

The mortgage interest rate has an inverse impact on apartment prices. A one percent decrease in mortgage interest rate leads to a 0.456 percent increase in apartment prices in Swedish cities but only a 0.095 percent increase in German cities. Estimation of mortgage interest rate impact in Sweden is similar to estimation result of −0.45 percent obtained for single-family house prices in study done by Adams and Fuss (2010). It is worth noting that the effect of the increase in mortgage interest rates might be different from the effect when decrease occurs. Claussen (2013) reported that an increase in the after tax real mortgage rate of one percentage point is associated with a reduction in the long run equilibrium level of the single-family house prices by 6 percent, while in Asal (2018) study this estimation was 8 percent and in Asal (2019) study 2 percent.

The results strongly confirm the theoretical implications of the DiPasquale and Wheaton (1992) model. However, individual effects vary widely among cities. For example, the effect of population growth on apartment prices in Gothenburg is about twice as large as in Stockholm and Malmö. Unemployment has a negative effect in Gothenburg, while positive in Malmö and is insignificant in Stockholm. The impact of unemployment is insignificant at the country level.

The results for the German dataset in Table 8 indicate that apartment stock, mortgage interest rate, and unemployment reduce apartment prices. Thus, a one percent increase in apartment stock leads to 2.4 percent decrease in apartment prices, while a one percent decrease in the mortgage interest rate leads to a 0.095 percent increase in apartment prices in German cities. The unemployment rate has a negative effect, though it is not that strong – only 0.43 percent.

The effect of the population variable was found insignificant for Germany. However, individual cities' effect varies a lot from a highly positive impact of 9.7 percent in Düsseldorf to minus 5.9 percent in Cologne and minus 5.8 percent in Frankfurt, which lies in line with previous research (Mankiw and Weil (1989)).

Comparison of results in Tables 7 and 8 provide evidence that the impact of Swedish fundamentals, in general, is much stronger than the impact of German fundamentals. However, if one is to compare the descriptive statistics of Swedish and German data (Tables 1 and 2), the size of fundamentals in both countries are quite similar. Moreover, the development of fundamentals over the long run are not able to explain the large difference of 759 percent in apartment price dynamics between two countries (Table 9). The population and disposable income that are drivers of apartment prices from the demand side were growing much faster in Swedish cities than in Germany, but the apartment stock that affects prices from the supply side also demonstrated much stronger growth. This would balance the pressure on housing prices from the demand and supply side. The mortgage interest rate was falling faster in German cities, and that drives apartment prices up, but the effect is quite moderate in comparison to Swedish cities.

6. Conclusions and policy implications

This study examines the impact of macroeconomic fundamentals on apartment prices in Germany and Sweden in the long run. The estimations presented in this paper lead to one important conclusion that is different from the studies done before: apartment price dynamics in Swedish cities differs, to a great extent, from those in German cities despite quite similar underlying development of fundamentals. The results have demonstrated that fundamental factors like population, disposable income, mortgage interest rate, and apartment stock determine the development of apartment prices in Sweden over the long term, but the reactions of the same factors are smaller in Germany.

Why do similar changes in fundamentals results in different long term dynamics of apartment prices in Germany and Sweden? One of the hypotheses might be that it might be the evidence of the price bubble building in Sweden. Another hypotheses might be that these two countries differ in institutional arrangements of the housing markets, and these arrangements might contribute to the size of apartment price elasticities from changes in fundamentals. These arrangements include various banking sector policies, such as mortgage financing and valuation approaches, as well as different government regulations of the housing market as, for example, rent control. A study of these institutional arrangements and their implications for housing price dynamics might be an interesting topic for further research.

Figures

Real house prices (Index: 1st quarter 1995 = 100)

Figure A1

Real house prices (Index: 1st quarter 1995 = 100)

Housing price dynamics in Sweden

Figure A2

Housing price dynamics in Sweden

Housing market structure by tenure type in Sweden

Figure A3

Housing market structure by tenure type in Sweden

Housing market structure by tenure type in Germany

Figure A4

Housing market structure by tenure type in Germany

Descriptive statistics for Swedish cities

Variable nameNumber of observationsMeanStandard deviation
Price for apartments per sq.m, SEK6924751.217221.7
Population, number of inhabitants871142741.0585846.9
Apartment stock in multifamily buildings, dwellings87141254.7108063.9
Total apartment stock per capita870.50.0
Disposable income per capita, thousands SEK69155.041.6
Mortgage interest rate, percent783.42.1
Unemployment rate, percent428.62.2

Descriptive statistics for German cities

Variable nameNumber of observationsMeanStandard deviation
Price for apartments per sq.m, Euro2032252.8889.9
Population, number of inhabitants203919487.4423730.5
Apartment stock in multifamily buildings, dwellings161154793.373324.5
Total apartment stock per capita1960.50.0
Disposable income per capita, Euro15420415.42963.5
Mortgage interest rate, percent1753.01.9
Unemployment rate, percent1478.62.4

Stationarity test for Swedish variables

VariablesLevelFirst difference
t-barp-valuet-barp-value
Apartment price per sq.m, SEK−1.67130.3654−3.7103***0.0006
Population, number of inhabitants0.17750.9998−2.2293*0.0838
Apartment stock in multifamily buildings, dwellings−0.60260.9683−2.5075**0.0333
Disposable income per capita, thousands SEK−2.11210.1284−5.1196***0.0000
Mortgage interest rate, percent−1.01750.6997−3.3777**0.0386
Unemployment rate, percent−2.5059*0.0600−4.8580***0.0004

Note(s): The IPS test is based on the individual ADF regressions with an intercept, trend, and the first lag of the dependent variable. The test statistic has an asymptotic standardized normal distribution

* denotes rejection of the null hypothesis of unit root based on their p-value at the 0.10 significance level

** denotes rejection of the null hypothesis of unit root based on their p-value at the 0.05 significance level

*** denotes rejection of the null hypothesis of unit root based on their p-value at the 0.01 significance level

Stationarity test for German variables

VariablesLevelFirst difference
t-barp-valuet-barp-value
Apartment price per sq.m, Euro−0.88550.9739−4.3016***0.0000
Population, number of inhabitants−0.43200.9996−4.3768***0.0000
Apartment stock in multifamily buildings, dwellings−1.62500.4004−2.7139***0.0009
Disposable income per capita, Euro−2.0931**0.0420−4.6199***0.0000
Mortgage interest rate, percent−0.97500.7166−4.4288**0.0118
Unemployment rate, percent−1.95080.1023−3.9213***0.0000

Note(s): The IPS test is based on the individual ADF regressions with an intercept, trend, and the first lag of the dependent variable. The test statistic has an asymptotic standardized normal distribution

** denotes rejection of the null hypothesis of unit root based on their p-value at the 0.05 significance level

*** denotes rejection of the null hypothesis of unit root based on their p-value at the 0.01 significance level

Pedroni (1999) test statistics for the Swedish dataset

Test statisticsPanelGroup
v−1.599
rho1.6432.388
t−5.480***−6.638***
ADF0.187−1.672**
Number of panel units3
Number of regressors5
Number of observations39

Note(s): Null Hypothesis: No cointegration. Time trend is included. Data have not been time-demeaned. Automatic lag length selection based on AIC [7]

All statistics are from Pedroni's procedure (1999), where the adjusted values can be compared to the N(0, 1) distribution. The Pedroni (2004) statistics are one-sided tests with a critical value of −1.64 (k < −1.64 implies rejection of the null), except the v-statistic that has a critical value of 1.64 (k > 1.64 suggests rejection of the null)

***, ** indicates rejection of the null hypothesis of “No cointegration” at 1% and 5%, levels of significance

Pedroni (1999) Test statistics for the German dataset

Test statisticsPanelGroup
v−0.688
rho1.7932.878
t−0.2570.006
ADF1.212−2.086**
Number of panel units7
Number of regressors5
Number of observations133

Note(s): Null Hypothesis: No cointegration. Time trend is not included. Data have been time-demeaned. Automatic lag length selection based on AIC

All statistics are from Pedroni's procedure (1999), where the adjusted values can be compared to the N(0, 1) distribution. The Pedroni (2004) statistics are one-sided tests with a critical value of −1.64 (k < −1.64 implies rejection of the null), except the v-statistic that has a critical value of 1.64 (k > 1.64 suggests rejection of the null)

** indicates rejection of the null hypothesis of “No cointegration” at 5% level of significance

DOLS estimates for Swedish cities

CityApartment stockPopulationDisposable incomeMortgage interest rateUnemployment rate
Coeft-statCoeft-statCoeft-statCoeft-statCoeft-stat
Stockholm2.158***49.947.332***11.881.921***17.55−0.358***−11.66−0.207*−1.43
Gothenburg3.681***19.9413.61***5.092.65***8.01−0.526***−21.11−0.916***−7.27
Malmö5.249***34.125.534***5.563.219***8.24−0.484***−17.190.689***6.44
Number of obs21 21 18 21 9
t-stat critical value at 1%, 5%, 10% significance leveldf = 192.539
1.729
1.328
df = 192.539
1.729
1.328
df = 162.583
1.746
1.337
df = 192.539
1.729
1.328
df = 72.998
1.895
1.415
Panel group DOLS (group mean average)
Coefficient3.696***60.048.826***13.012.597***19.51−0.456***−28.84−0.145−1.31
Number of obs63 63 54 63 27
t-stat critical value at 1%, 5%, 10% significance leveldf = 612.390
1.671
1.296
df = 612.390
1.671
1.296
df = 522.423
1.684
1.303
df = 612.390
1.671
1.296
df = 252.485
1.708
1.316

Note(s): * and *** represent significance at error levels of 10% and 1%, respectively

DOLS estimates for German cities

CityApartment stockPopulationDisposable incomeMortgage interest rateUnemployment rate
Coeft-statCoeft-statCoeft-statCoeft-statCoeft-stat
Bremen2.337***11.482.152***4.01−3.879**−2.35−0.045*−1.590.050.30
Cologne−0.937***−7.41−5.92***−8.692.564***3.67−0.073***−3.140.871.03
Düsseldorf−2.377***−7.179.697***8.641.4941.08−0.061**−2.54−1.602***−5.14
Frankfurt (main)−1.929**−1.82−5.83***−6.122.739***3.29−0.084***−5.791.119***3.4
Hamburg−3.817−1.15−3.657***−6.121.5211.23−0.122***−3.66−1.464**−2.22
Munich−7.32−0.403.339***6.870.040.04−0.178***−5.43−3.463***−4.73
Stuttgart−2.565**−2.480.1870.142.2691.33−0.104***−4.181.502***3.27
Number of obs18 24 17 20 16
t-stat critical value at 1%, 5%, 10% significance leveldf = 162.583
1.746
1.337
df = 222.508
1.717
1.321
df = 152.602
1.753
1.341
df = 182.552
1.734
1.330
df = 142.624
1.761
1.345
Panel group DOLS (group mean average)
Coefficient−2.373***−3.39−0.004−0.480.964***3.13−0.095***−9.95−0.427*−1.55
Number of obs126 168 119 140 112
t-stat critical value at 1%, 5%, 10% significance leveldf = 1242.358
1.658
1.289
df = 1662.358
1.658
1.289
df = 1172.364
1.660
1.290
df = 1382.358
1.658
1.289
df = 1102.368
1.662
1.291

Note(s): *, **, and *** represent significance at error levels of 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively

Long run development of fundamentals in Swedish and German cities

VariablesTime periodSwedish citiesGerman citiesDifference
Total growth, %Per annum, %Total growth, %Per annum, %Total growth, %Per annum, %
Price for apartments per sq.m, SEK1996–2016831.8411.5772.822.68759.028.89
Population, number of inhabitants1996–201625.751.159.780.4615.970.69
Apartment stock in multifamily buildings, dwellings1996–201673.882.7226.501.1847.381.54
Disposable income per capita, (thousands SEK/Euro)1996–2016120.064.0239.201.6780.862.35
Mortgage interest rate, percent1996–2016−85.67−4.30−100.03−5.0314.360.73
Unemployment rate, percent2005–2016−10.42−0.95−39.66−3.6129.242.66

Variables definitions and data sources

VariableDefinitionUnitData source
Apartment priceReal apartment price per square meter (average)EUR (Germany)
SEK (Sweden)
National Statistical Bureau and Mäklarstatistik (Sweden)
BulweinGesa AG (Germany)
PopulationTotal number of inhabitantsPersonNational Statistical Bureau (Sweden)
BulweinGesa AG (Germany)
Apartment stock in multifamily buildingsTotal apartments stock (existing and new construction)Number of dwelling unitsNational Statistical Bureau (Sweden)
BulweinGesa AG (Germany)
Disposable income per capitaReal disposable income of private personsThousands SEK (Sweden)
EUR (Germany)
National Statistical Bureau (Sweden)
BulweinGesa AG (Germany)
Mortgage interest rateInterest rate for mortgage borrowingPercentRiksbanken and Swedbank (Sweden)
Deutsche Bundesbank (Germany)
Unemployment rateUnemployed persons as proportion in a total labour forcePercentNational Statistical Bureau (Sweden)
BulweinGesa AG (Germany)

Notes

1.

See section 2 for research overview on macroeconomic determinats of housing prices.

2.

The search for housing price determinants studies was done using the Royal Institute of Technology (Sweden) library catalogue, which includes over 100 databases and subscriptions to over 11,000 e-journals as well as a large number of open access resources.

3.

For extended research overview in housing and macroeconomics see, for example, studies done by Leung (2004), Panagiotidis and Printzis (2016), Piazzesi and Schneider (2016).

4.

Taking into account that the exchange rate between Swedish krona and Euro fluctuated between 8.5 and 10 SEK to 1 Euro over the last two decades (Source: ECB), the simple calculation of economic variables in both countries into the same currency allows the conclusion to be drawn that underlying fundamentals presented in Tables 1 and 2 are very similar in both countries.

5.

At the same time cities of the same countries might be heterogeneous due to local socio-economic differences.

6.

For the effects of supply elasticity on house prices see, for example, studies done by Glaeser et al. (2008) and Oikarinen et al. (2018). They provide evidence that lower supply elasticity caused larger and longer price bubbles in the 2000s. However, the study done by Davidoff (2013) concludes that there is no evidence that differences in supply elasticity caused different reactions in house prices in the USA during the 2000s housing cycle. Hort (1998) explains that “The long-run supply of housing is likely to be an increasing function of the level of house prices for two reasons. First, since the supply of urban land is fixed, land prices tend to increase with the size of the urban housing stock, i.e. as land for development becomes more scarce. Second, unless the production possibility frontier between structures and other goods is flat, the long-run equilibrium price of new structures will be an increasing function of demand.” (Hort, 1998, p. 95)

7.

Akaike's information criterion (AIC) is used to estimate the autoregressive lag length. It is superior to the other criteria under study in the case of a small sample in the way that it minimizes the chance of under estimation while maximizing the chance of recovering the true lag length (Khim-Sen (2004)).

8.

p is usually chosen to be around 2 for annual observations.

Appendix 1
Appendix 2
Appendix 3

References

Abraham, J. and Hendershott, P. (1996), “Bubbles in metropolitan housing markets”, Journal of Housing Research, Vol. 7 No. 2, pp. 191-207.

Adams, Z. and Füss, R. (2010), “Macroeconomic determinants of international housing markets”, Journal of Housing Economics, Vol. 19 No. 1, pp. 38-50.

Asal, M. (2018), “Long-run drivers and short-term dynamics of Swedish real house prices”, International Journal of Housing Markets, Vol. 11 No. 1, pp. 45-72.

Asal, M. (2019), “Is there a bubble in the Swedish housing market”, Journal of European Real Estate Research, Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 32-61.

Baffoe-Bonnie, J. (1998), “The dynamic impact of macroeconomic aggregates on housing prices and stock of houses: a national and regional analysis”, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 17 No. 2, pp. 179-97.

Belke, A. and Keil, J. (2018), “Fundamental determinants of real estate prices: a panel study of German regions”, International Advances in Economic Research, No. 24, pp. 25-45.

Berg, L. (2002), “Prices on the second-hand market for Swedish family houses: correlation, causation and determinants”, European Journal of Housing Policy, Vol. 2 No. 1, pp. 1-24.

Caldera Sánchez, C. and Johansson, Å. (2011), The Price Responsiveness of Housing Supply in OECD Countries, OECD Economics Department working papers, No. 837, OECD Publishing.

Cameron, G., Muellbauer, J. and Murphy, A. (2006), Was There a British House Price Bubble? Evidence from a Regional Panel, discussion paper series, No. 276, University of Oxford, Department of Economics, ISSN, 1471-0498.

Capozza, D., Hendershott, P., Mack, C. and Mayer, C. (2004), “Determinants of real house price dynamics”, Journal of Real Estate Economics, No. 2, pp. 1-32.

Case, K. and Shiller, R. (1990), “Forecasting prices and excess returns in the housing market”, Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, Vol. 18 No. 3, pp. 253-73.

Case, K. and Shiller, R. (2003), “Is there a bubble in the housing market?”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 2003 No. 2, pp. 299-342.

Claussen, A.C. (2013), “Are Swedish houses overpriced?”, International Journal of Housing Markets and Analysis, Vol. 6 No. 2, pp. 180-196.

Colwell, P.F. (2002), “Tweaking the DiPasquale-Wheaton model”, Journal of Housing Economics, Vol. 11 No. 1, pp. 24-39.

Davidoff, T. (2013), “Supply elasticity and the housing cycle of the 2000s”, Real Estate Economics, Vol. 41 No. 4, pp. 793-813.

DiPasquale, D. and Wheaton, W. (1992), “The markets for real estate assets and space: a conceptual framework”, Journal of American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, Vol. 20 No. 1, pp. 181-197.

Duca, J., Muellbauer, J. and Murphy, A. (2011), Shifting Credit Standards and the Boom and Bust in US House Prices, working paper No.1104, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Research Department.

Dust, L. and Maening, W. (2007), Shrinking and Growing Metropolitan Areas – Asymmetric Real Estate Price Reactions? the Case of German Single-Family Houses, Hamburg Working Paper Series in Economic Policy, No. 06, ISBN, 978-3-940369-27-7.

Engle, R. and Granger, C. (1987), “Co-integration and error-correction: representation, estimation and testing”, Econometrica, Vol. 55 No. 5, pp. 251-276.

Englund, P. and Ioannides, Y. (1997), “House price dynamics: an international empirical perspective”, Journal of Housing Economics, Vol. 6 No. 2, pp. 119-136.

Gallin, J. (2006), “The long-run relationship between house prices and income: evidence from local housing markets”, Real Estate Economics, Vol. 34 No. 3, pp. 417-438.

Girouard, N., Kennedy, M., van den Noord, P. and Andre, C. (2006), Recent House Price Developmens: The Role of Fundamentals, Working Paper, No. 475, OECD.

Giussani, B. and Hadjimatheou, G. (1992), “House prices: an econometric model for the UK”, Netherlands Journal of Housing and the Built Environment, Vol. 7 No. 1, pp. 31-58.

Glaeser, E.L., Gyourko, J. and Saiz, A. (2008), “Housing supply and housing bubbles”, Journal of Urban Economics, No. 2, pp. 198-217.

Himmelberg, C., Mayer, C. and Sinai, T. (2005), “Assessing high house prices: bubbles, fundamentals and misperceptions”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 19 No. 4, pp. 67-92.

Hort, K. (1998), “The determinants of urban house price fluctuations in Sweden 1968-1994”, Journal of Housing Economics, Vol. 7 No. 2, pp. 93-120.

Hwang, M. and Quigley, J. (2006), “Economic fundamentals in local housing markets: evidence from US metropolitan regions”, Journal of Regional Science, Vol. 46 No. 3, pp. 425-453.

Im, K., Pesaran, M. and Shin, Y. (2003), “Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 115, pp. 53-74.

Inder, B. (1993), “Estimating long-run relationships in economics: a comparison of different approaches”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 57 Nos 1–3, pp. 53-68.

Jones, G. and Hyslak, T. (1999), “House prices and regional labor markets”, The Annals of Regional Science, No. 33, pp. 33-49.

Jud, D. and Winkler, D. (2002), “The dynamics of metropolitan housing prices”, Journal of Real Estate Research, Vol. 44 No. 1, pp. 29-45.

Kajuth, F., Knetsch, T. and Pinkwart, N. (2013), Assessing House Prices in Germany: Evidence from an Estimated Stock-Flow Model Using Regional Data, Discussion Paper, No. 46/2013, Deutsche Bundesbank.

Kao, C. and Chiang, M. (2000), “On the estimation and inference of a cointegrated regression in panel data”, in Baltagi, B.H. (Ed.), Advances in Econometrics: Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration and Dynamic Panels, Elsevier Science, Vol. 15, pp. 179-222.

Khim-Sen, V. (2004), “Which lag length selection criteria should we employ?”, Economics Bulletin, AccessEcon, Vol. 3 No. 33, pp. 1-9.

Koetter, M. and Poghosyan, T. (2010), “Real estate prices and bank stability”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 34 No. 6, pp. 1129-1138.

Kundan Kishor, N. and Marfatis, H. (2017), “The dynamic relationship between housing prices and the macroeconomy: evidence from OECD Countries”, Journal of Real Estate Finance Economics, No. 54, pp. 237-268.

Leung, C. (2004), “Macroeconomics and housing: a review of the literature”, Journal of Housing Economics, Vol. 13 No. 4, pp. 249-267.

Lind, H. (2009), “Price bubbles in housing markets Concept, theory and indicators”, International Journal of Housing Markets and Analysis, Vol. 2 No. 1, pp. 78-90.

Mankiw, G. and Weil, D. (1989), “The baby boom, the baby boost and the housing market”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, Vol. 19 No. 2, pp. 235-258.

Mark, N. and Sul, D. (2003), “Cointegration vector estimation by panel DOLS and long-run money demand”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 65 No. 5, pp. 655-680.

McCarthy, J. and Peach, R. (2004), “Are home prices the next bubble?”, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, Federal Reserve Bank of, New York, December.

Meen, G. (2002), “The time series behavior of house prices: a transatlantic divide”, Journal of Housing Economics, Vol. 11 No. 1, pp. 1-23.

Mikhed, V. and Zemčik, P. (2009), “Do house prices reflect fundamentals?”, Journal of Housing Economics, Vol. 18 No. 2, pp. 140-149.

Miles, D. and Pillonca, V. (2008), “Financial innovation and European housing and mortgage markets”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Oxford University Press, Vol. 24 No. 1, pp. 145-175.

Muellbauer, J. and Murphy, A. (1994), Explaining Regional House Prices in the UK, Department of Economics Working Paper No. 94/29, University College Dublin.

Oikarinen, E., Bourassa, S.C., Hoesli, M. and Engblom, J. (2018), “US metropolitan house price dynamics”, Journal of Urban Economics, No. 105, pp. 54-69.

Ozanne, L. and Thibodeau, T. (1983), “Explaining metropolitan housing price differences”, Journal of Urban Economics, No. 13, pp. 51-66.

Panagiotidis, T. and Printzis, P. (2016), “On the macroeconomic determinants of the housing market in Greece: a VECM approach”, International Economics and Economic Policy, No. 13, pp. 387-409.

Pedroni, P. (1999), “Critical values for cointegration tests in heterogeneous panels with multiple regressors”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 61 No. 4, pp. 653-670.

Pedroni, P. (2000), “Fully modified OLS for heterogeneous cointegrated panels”, Advances in Econometrics, Vol. 15, pp. 93-130.

Pedroni, P. (2004), “Panel cointegration; asymptotic and finite sample properties of pooled time series tests, with an application to the PPP hypothesis”, Econometric Theory, Vol. 20 No. 3, pp. 597-625.

Phillips, P. and Moon, H. (1999), “Linear regression limit theory for nonstationary panel data”, Econometrica, Vol. 67 No. 5, pp. 1057-1111.

Piazzesi, M. and Schneider, M. (2016), “Housing and macroeconomics”, in Taylor, J. and Uhlig, H. (Eds), Handbook of Macroeconomics, 2B Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 1547-1640.

Poterba, J. (1991), “House price dynamics: the role of tax policy and demography”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 2, pp. 143-203.

Quigley, J. (1999), “Real estate prices and economic cycles”, International Real Estate Review, Vol. 2 No. 1, pp. 1-20.

Reichert, A. (1990), “The impact of interest rates, income, and employment upon regional housing prices”, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 3 No. 4, pp. 373-391.

Saikkonen, P. (1991), “Asymptotically efficient estimation of cointegration regressions”, Econometric Theory, Vol. 7 No. 1, pp. 1-21.

Sivitanides, P. (2018), “Macroeconomic drivers of London house prices”, Journal of Property Investment and Finance, Vol. 36 No. 6, pp. 539-551.

Stock, J. and Watson, M. (1993), “A simple estimator of cointegrating vectors in higher order integrated systems”, Econometrica, Vol. 61 No. 4, pp. 783-820.

Taltavull de La Paz, P. and White, M. (2012), “Fundamental drivers of house price change: the role of money, mortgages and migration in Spain and the United Kingdom”, Journal of Property Research, Vol. 29 No. 4, pp. 341-367.

Terrones, M. and Otrok, T. (2004), “The global house price boom”, Chapter II in the “World Economic Outlook: The Global Demographic Transition. A Survey by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, September, available at: https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WEO/Issues/2016/12/31/The-Global-Demographic-Transition.

Turner, B. (1997), “Housing cooperatives in Sweden: the effect of financial deregulation”, Journal of Real Estate and Finance and Economics, Vol. 15 No. 2, pp. 193-217.

Wheaton, W. and Nechayev, G. (2008), “The 1998-2005 housing ‘bubble’ and the current ‘correction’: what's different this time?”, Journal of Real Estate Research, Vol. 30 No. 1, pp. 1-26.

White, M. (2015), “Cyclical and structural change in the UK housing market”, Journal of European Real Estate Research, Vol. 8 No. 1, pp. 85-103.

Wilhelmsson, M. (2008), “Regional house prices. An application of two equation model to the Swedish housing market”, International Journal of Housing, Vol. 1 No. 1, pp. 33-51.

Xu, L. and Tang, B. (2014), “On the determinants of UK house prices”, International Journal of Economics and Research, Vol. 5 No. 2, pp. 57-64.

Yang, Z., Wang, S. and Campbell, R. (2010), “Monetary policy and regional price boom in Sweden”, Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 32 No. 6, pp. 865-879.

Acknowledgements

This paper is financed by the research project Bostad 2.0 (Housing 2.0) at the Royal Institute of Technology KTH.

Corresponding author

Sviatlana Engerstam can be contacted at: sviatlana.engerstam@abe.kth.se

Related articles