The role of headquarters in managing coopetition within MNCs: a tale of two paradoxes

Roger Schweizer (Department of Business Administration, School of Business, Economics and Law, University of Gothenburg, Gothenburg, Sweden)
Katarina Lagerström (Department of Business Studies, Uppsala University, Gävle, Sweden)
Emilene Leite (School of Business, Örebro University, Orebro, Sweden)
Cecilia Pahlberg (Department of Business Studies, Uppsala University, Gävle, Sweden)

Multinational Business Review

ISSN: 1525-383X

Article publication date: 30 October 2023

254

Abstract

Purpose

The purpose of this paper is to contribute to the discussion on how multinational company (MNC) headquarters (HQs) can manage the existing coopetition paradox to ensure innovation within the MNC. In contrast to the rather scarce previous research, the authors argue that HQ needs to solve the coopetition paradox under the sway of a parenting paradox. Hence, HQ faces a dual paradox.

Design/methodology/approach

Drawing on the literature on HQ’s role during MNCs’ innovation processes, this conceptual paper revisits the previously suggested HQ measures to enable coopetition among subsidiaries. By applying a sheer ignorance perspective, the authors contribute with a more nuanced understanding of the HQ’s role in innovation activities.

Findings

The article identifies four challenges as the HQ faces a parenting paradox that hinders its ability to solve the coopetition paradox: context specificity of subsidiaries’ innovation work, normative expectations of subsidiary managers, potential opportunistic behavior of HQ manager and HQ underestimation of needed resources. The article suggests that HQ needs to become more informed and preferably even embedded in the local innovation networks of its most important subsidiaries and that coopetition should not be managed solely on an HQ level.

Originality/value

Advocating a sheer ignorance perspective, the article pioneers in discussing the role that HQ plays in managing coopetition among subsidiaries in innovation activities.

Keywords

Citation

Schweizer, R., Lagerström, K., Leite, E. and Pahlberg, C. (2023), "The role of headquarters in managing coopetition within MNCs: a tale of two paradoxes", Multinational Business Review, Vol. ahead-of-print No. ahead-of-print. https://doi.org/10.1108/MBR-11-2022-0175

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2023, Roger Schweizer, Katarina Lagerström, Emilene Leite and Cecilia Pahlberg.

License

Licensed re-use rights only


1. Introduction

Recent decades have seen an increasing research interest in coopetition – that is, simultaneous cooperation and competition between at least two actors (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000, 2014; Raza-Ullah et al., 2014; Ritala and Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, 2009). Most of these studies have focused on coopetition between firms, while coopetition within firms has attained less attention (Hong and Snell, 2015; Luo, 2005; Tippmann et al., 2018). In this paper, we add to the intrafirm studies by addressing coopetition within multinational companies (MNCs). Previous research on competition and cooperation within MNCs has mainly focused on why competition and cooperation exist in general (Luo, 2005, 2007; Luo et al., 2006), while only a few studies have addressed the question of how these contradictory forces are managed (Lagerström et al., 2021, 2023). We contribute by discussing the complexity related to how headquarters (HQs) manages the simultaneous quest for competitive and cooperative – that is, coopetition – activities across their geographically dispersed subsidiaries.

This complexity is of specific interest when it comes to innovation, a key activity for the competitive advantage of firms (Ciabuschi et al., 2017). As innovation processes are largely context-specific (Andersson et al., 2007; Asakawa, 2001) and increasingly emanate from subsidiaries (Phene and Almeida, 2008; Strutzenberger and Ambos, 2014), HQ is expected to manage a complex system of interdependent subsidiaries in a differentiated network (Ghoshal and Bartlett, 1990). In such a system, subsidiaries involved in their local networks must compete for HQs resources and attention while also cooperating to fulfil overall organizational goals.

By planning and coordinating this interdependent network, HQ sets a context that promotes or inhibits coopetition. Coopetition, which refers to both competition and cooperation between subsidiaries, is necessary to enhance innovation in MNCs (Cerrato, 2006; Gammelgaard, 2009; Luo et al., 2006). However, the contradicting nature of the two mechanisms of competition and cooperation indicates substantial challenges with regard to governance (Lagerström et al., 2023). Hence, managing coopetition means finding a solution to an inherent paradox (Bengtsson and Kock, 2014; Gnyawali and Park, 2011) – the coopetition paradox.

Luo (2005) proposed a variety of measures HQ can take to manage coopetition, such as creating and coordinating a favorable organizational infrastructure and trusting a steering executive committee at the HQ level to foster knowledge sharing among subsidiaries. However, these measures build on the presumed existence of a parenting advantage, suggesting that HQ adds value when involving itself in subsidiary activities (Goold and Campbell, 2002; Poppo, 2003). HQ is also argued to be capable of monitoring the innovation process at the subsidiary level – albeit from a distance – and decisively shaping the innovation process through formal and informal control and coordination mechanisms (Ciabuschi et al., 2012; Luo, 2005). However, Luo (2005) acknowledges that potential challenges exist in relation to managing coopetition among subsidiaries, as HQ might lack crucial knowledge of innovation processes at the local level and may therefore be limited in its ability to contribute to the processes (Ciabuschi et al., 2012). A related aspect adding to the challenges is the lack of ability at HQ to recognize the value of the innovative knowledge for the MNC and then to assimilate and make use of it on a broader scale – that is, the lack of absorptive capacity (Adenfelt and Lagerström, 2006; Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; Schleimer and Pedersen, 2014). However, it has been argued that HQ can overcome these challenges through appropriate organizational forms (Luo, 2005; Goold et al., 1994, 1998) and by drawing on the combinative capabilities at disposal: systems capabilities, coordination capabilities and socialization capabilities (Van den Bosch et al., 1999; Grant, 1996; Kogut and Zander, 1992).

HQ’s ability to manage subsidiaries has been further questioned by researchers highlighting that HQ suffers from “sheer ignorance” (Ciabuschi et al., 2012; Ciabuschi et al., 2015; Su et al., 2021). Ciabuschi et al. (2012) explain that, within a sheer ignorance perspective, MNCs are understood as distributed knowledge systems where knowledge is context-specific. Cuervo-Cazurra and Narula (2015, p. 7) add that “firms and their managers are not fully rational, and they cannot possibly have full information of all the alternatives.” Furthermore, while knowledge is mainly action-oriented, it is also collectively shared in a complicated system that no individual understands in its entirety (Tsoukas, 1996). Consequently, HQ not only has incomplete knowledge but also does not know what it needs to know (Tsoukas, 1996). As noted by Ciabuschi et al. (2012), a primary challenge for HQ is not only the lack of knowledge about subsidiaries’ innovation processes but also the lack of awareness that it lacks such knowledge. Consequently, the view that HQ has a parenting advantage might need to be reconsidered, with attention given to the observation that HQ’s direct involvement in innovation activities at the subsidiary level might even hamper the performance of these processes, resulting in a parenting paradox (Ciabuschi et al., 2017).

In sum, HQ’s ability to design an efficient coopetition system that controls and coordinates its subsidiaries to spur innovation within the MNC is rather limited (Barner-Rasmussen et al., 2010; Ciabuschi et al., 2011a, 2011b; Collis et al., 2007; Denrell et al., 2004; Forsgren and Holm, 2010; Goold and Campbell, 2002). Although HQ’s involvement is intended to add value, its interventions might also have negative effects. Hence, we put forward that HQ needs to solve the coopetition paradox under the sway of a parenting paradox. Considering these paradoxes, the aim of this conceptual paper is to give a more nuanced view of how HQ can manage coopetition to ensure innovation within the MNC. Accordingly, drawing on the HQ’s role during MNC innovation processes, we revisit the previously suggested HQ measures to enable coopetition among subsidiaries applying a sheer ignorance perspective.

We continue with a review of the research on coopetition within MNCs, with a particular focus on innovation activities. Thereafter, we address the prevailing view on how HQ can manage coopetition with the limitations portrayed in a sheer ignorance perspective and present a variety of challenges faced by HQ in the endeavor to drive innovation by designing and managing coopetition among subsidiaries. Finally, we offer suggestions for overcoming these challenges.

2. Coopetition within multinational companies: managing a paradox

The current international business literature puts an MNC’s ability to innovate on par with its ability to manage the paradox of coopetition – namely, the simultaneous quest for competitive and cooperative activities across geographically dispersed subsidiaries (Hong and Snell, 2015; Luo, 2005; Tippmann et al., 2018). Such a paradox exists as innovations within most contemporary MNCs originate not only from the parent organization but also, and increasingly, from innovation activities carried out at subsidiaries (Birkinshaw and Hood, 1998; Lagerström et al., 2019; Phene and Almeida, 2008; Reilly et al., 2023) as a result of their close relationships with local external actors – that is, their external embeddedness (Dellestrand, 2011; Ferraris, 2014; Nell and Ambos, 2013).

An additional facet is that subsidiaries also compete with each other for limited resources, mandates and attention from the parent company (Becker-Ritterspach and Dörrenbächer, 2011; Birkinshaw and Morrison, 1995; O'Riordan et al., 2023; Strutzenberger and Ambos, 2014), yet they also need to collaborate with each other to drive innovation and, as a result, achieve collective gains (Luo, 2005; Rabbiosi and Santangelo, 2013). In cases where a subsidiary, either on its own or in collaboration with other subsidiaries, develops new innovative knowledge, it still has to be recognized and acknowledged by HQ to gain favors from HQ such as more resources or extended mandates. This is not a guaranteed outcome, as HQ might decide in favor of another subsidiary (Dörrenbächer and Gammelgaard, 2006; Egelhoff, 2010) for what it perceives to be the overall good of the MNC (Goold et al., 1998; Goold and Campbell, 2002). HQ and subsidiaries may have different views on their roles, importance and identities in the MNC, and thus, their motives and goals with engaging in innovative activities within the MNC might differ (Dörrenbächer and Gammelgaard, 2006). In line with the parenting argument, HQ is more likely to focus on creating common value for the MNC as a whole, whereas subsidiaries are more likely to focus on realizing greater value for themselves (Khanna et al., 1998), even if they also contribute to the MNC and to other subsidiaries (Asmussen et al., 2009; Reilly et al., 2023). Consequently, knowledge creation takes place within both competitive and cooperative relationships (Gammelgaard, 2009; Luo et al., 2006), and a paradox is thus likely to exist regarding not only how to govern innovation activities in MNCs but also how to use the innovation.

Based on the work of Gnyawali et al. (2016), three critical dualities exist that explain the difficulties experienced when trying to manage the coopetition paradox in relation to the governance of innovations. First, there may be competing priorities between HQ and subsidiaries on how to use an innovation developed within the MNC’s innovation system, as subsidiaries may want to appropriate a greater share for their own self-interests (Lavie, 2007; Ritala and Hurmelinna-Lukkanen, 2009), which risks limiting joint innovation activities. Furthermore, various types of contradictions are likely to emerge when two partners that differ from each other (Gnyawali et al., 2016) and have different motives interact. From an MNC perspective, subsidiaries might engage in innovation collaborations with other subsidiaries (Rabbiosi and Santangelo, 2013) and/or with HQ with the aim of introducing new products from a jointly developed technology, while other subsidiaries and/or HQ may be more interested in licensing the technology to external parties. Hence, differences can exist in their economic interests, underlying strategy and/or understanding of their role in innovation cooperation (Gnyawali and Park, 2011).

Second, subsidiaries might carefully define the depth and breadth of an innovation collaboration in an effort to work closely with HQ or other subsidiaries to create value, but not so closely as to become vulnerable (Ciabuschi et al., 2015). Finding this balance is a delicate task that differs not only from subsidiary to subsidiary but also over time. Thus, it is not uncommon that subsidiaries’ innovation ventures stretch the boundaries of their given mandates, and the extension of a subsidiary’s role can be identified by the degree to which it cooperates and the degree to which it competes on specific mandates with other subsidiaries (Tippmann et al., 2018), leading subsidiaries to question existing power positions and schemata within the MNC (Strutzenberger and Ambos, 2014). Hence, HQ and subsidiaries are cautious when entering any form of innovation collaboration as are also sister subsidiaries as they compete for resources and mandates (Birkinshaw and Hood, 1998; Cantwell and Mudambi, 2005; O'Riordan et al., 2023).

Third, as competition and cooperation interactions are incompatible (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000), subsidiaries might temporally and/or spatially separate between cooperating and competing in innovations based on the outcome of such innovation work. Tippmann et al. (2018), for example, argue that subsidiaries apply a competitive frame when emphasizing a desire to gain or win superiority over other MNC units, whereas they apply a cooperative frame emphasizing joint work with other subsidiaries to reach common corporate-level goals or predetermined objectives set for them. Subsidiaries are able to move from one frame to another, although they pass an intermittent assessment of the appropriateness of their current frame, also known as a comparative pivot (Tippmann et al., 2018). Thus, managing coopetition means that HQ needs to be able to manage these frames.

Gnyawali et al. (2016) suggest that coopetition is managed more effectively if firms have adequate analytical and executional (i.e. managerial) capabilities. Relating to HQ’s ambition to manage coopetition, analytical capabilities refer to its ability to understand how the above-discussed contradictions and dualities impact its relationship with its subsidiaries as well as the relationships among the subsidiaries in the MNC. In other words, HQ’s capability to realize that both cooperation and competition are beneficial facilitates the acceptance of dualities (Oliver, 2004).

Moreover, the management of coopetition is complex and tests both HQ’s and subsidiaries’ capabilities to process information and anticipate future scenarios, as it is associated with strategic novelty and innovativeness (Gnyawali et al., 2016). Previous experience of coopetition has thus been shown to result in abilities to better comprehend the complex interplay between competition and cooperation (Gnyawali et al., 2016), consequently making it easier to manage. In other words, previous experience of coopetition has a positive impact on HQ’s ability to productively manage the tension in a coopetition relationship in the MNC, as such experience is instrumental in developing and leveraging appropriate structures and routines to govern these relationships (Lagerström et al., 2021; Gnyawali et al., 2016).

The management of coopetition relationships is also crucial for innovation activities because of the relational resources and advantages that stem from such relationships (Dyer and Singh, 1998). In the MNC literature, a distinction is made between two forms of innovation activities (Luo, 2005). The first is arranged and monitored by HQ and often takes the form of centrally coordinated R&D consortia, technology exchange, equipment relocation, resource redeployment and rotation of engineers. The second consists of innovation activities that are not planned and organized by HQ but, rather, that occur on a voluntary basis between subsidiaries through, for example, resource deployment and technology and knowledge exchange. These collaborative innovation activities take place even though the subsidiaries compete with each other for scarce resources and status (Cerrato, 2006; Hamel, 1991; Raza-Ullah et al., 2014). The resources they compete for range from technology, equipment and key talents to capital, supplies and know-how (Luo, 2005). A subsidiary’s ability to attract resources for innovation is both the result of and dependent on its strategic position within the MNC’s innovation system (Becker-Ritterspach and Dörrenbächer, 2011), implying that coopetition can be built among geographically dispersed knowledgeable subsidiaries (Luo, 2005; Tsai, 2002), among which the degree of coopetition (i.e. high/low competition and high/low cooperation) is determined by the degree of commonalities among the innovation activities.

HQ can take a variety of measures to enable and encourage coopetition within MNCs as a means to encourage innovation among subsidiaries (Lagerström et al., 2023; Luo, 2005; Tippmann et al., 2018; Tsai, 2002). First, HQ needs to create and effectively coordinate a favorable organizational infrastructure, including information sharing and reward systems, as well as routines for encoding, storing and converting knowledge into a retrievable and sharable form (Grant, 1996; Kogut and Zander, 1996; Madhok, 1996; Tsai, 2002). Van den Bosch et al. (1999), for example, demonstrate not only the importance of the organization form for developing knowledge and making it usable by others but also the crucial roles the three types of combinative capabilities play in making it to happen (Kogut and Zander, 1992). The systems capabilities in terms of direction, policies and procedures are likely more important for explicit knowledge, while coordination and socialization capabilities arguably are more important for the innovative knowledge. However, Kogut and Zander (1992, p. 391) point out that “new learning, such as innovations, are products of a firm’s combinative capabilities to generate new applications from existing knowledge.”

Second, coordination can be managed by an executive committee at the HQ level that meets periodically to plan, coordinate, monitor and appraise both cooperation and competition between subsidiaries (Luo, 2005). The task of such a committee is to create and maintain a climate to foster knowledge sharing, as well as to avoid duplication of innovation activities (Luo, 2005). The HQ committee can use formal mechanisms of coordination (e.g. centralization, formalization and/or specialization) but also – and perhaps preferably, given the complexity of governing innovation activities – more voluntary and personal informal mechanisms, such as interpersonal relations between subsidiary managers (Martinez and Jarillo, 1989; Tsai, 2002). Fostering social interactions across subsidiaries stimulates the formation of common interests and supports the building of new cooperative exchange relationships; thus, it is important for HQ to encourage such relationships, even if they also occur naturally across subsidiaries (Luo, 2005; Tsai and Ghoshal, 1998).

The above-described activities originate from a perspective on the MNC wherein HQ plays a vital role in building and managing a coopetitive innovation system built on the integration of various parts of the MNC. HQ is assumed to have an accurate understanding of the resources and knowledge on which the subsidiaries should compete to innovate and on which they should cooperate (Luo, 2005). Building on Ciabuschi et al.’s (2012) discussion of the involvement of HQ in subsidiaries’ innovation activities, it can be argued that HQ’s management of coopetition enhances legitimacy and provides structure and guidance for subsidiaries’ innovation activities, thereby also enhancing the subsidiaries’ performance (Poppo, 2003). Numerous researchers acknowledge that HQ creates value and thus has what is termed a parenting advantage (Egelhoff, 2010; Nell and Ambos, 2013), which in turn suggests that HQ can evaluate which subsidiary innovation processes to support (Egelhoff, 2010; Foss, 1997; Luo, 2005) as well as which outcomes of innovation activities to share throughout the MNC (Ciabuschi et al., 2017; Goold et al., 1998) and/or to exploit in a few selected locations (Ambos and Mahnke, 2010; Bouquet et al., 2009). However, this perspective on the role of HQ is not without criticism. There is considerable research advocating a sheer ignorance perspective questioning HQ’s ability to create and manage an efficient coopetition system that controls and coordinates its subsidiaries to spur innovation within the MNC (Barner-Rasmussen et al., 2010; Ciabuschi et al., 2011a; Collis et al., 2007; Denrell et al., 2004; Goold and Campbell, 2002). In other words, when managing the coopetition paradox, HQ must do so under the sway of a parenting paradox. Next, we discuss how the parenting paradox – that is, an understanding of HQ’s role in the contemporary MNC based on the premise that HQ faces the liabilities of outsidership (Vahlne et al., 2012) and sheer ignorance (Ciabuschi et al., 2012) – influences and hinders HQ’s ability to manage coopetition in the MNC to foster innovation at subsidiaries. We highlight various challenges and hinderances but also offer some potential solutions.

3. Managing the coopetition paradox under the sway of the parenting paradox

A first challenge HQ faces when seeking to solve the coopetition paradox lies in the fact that subsidiaries’ innovation work is often context-specific due to the subsidiaries’ embeddedness in their local networks (Birkinshaw, 1997; Cantwell and Mudambi, 2005 Ciabuschi et al.,2014, 2017; Ferraris, 2014). Hence, the very reason coopetition in innovation activities needs to have a well-functioning innovation climate, processes and structures is also the main hinderance experienced by HQ when attempting to organize and manage innovation through coopetition. HQ’s lack of knowledge of the subsidiary situation and network (i.e. sheer ignorance) result in a lack of understanding of the appropriate role to play in the innovation activities (Ciabuschi et al., 2012), as well as difficulty ascertaining in which activities subsidiaries should cooperate and over which resources they should compete (Lagerström et al., 2021). In a similar vein, Vahlne et al. (2012) highlight that HQ often faces a liability of outsidership in relation to subsidiaries’ local networks and, therefore, lacks adequate legitimacy. As a result, it is likely that HQ’s attempts to organize and manage coopetitive innovation activities might actually hamper a subsidiary’s innovation performance. In other words, HQ’s endeavor to influence subsidiaries toward competitive or cooperative behavior runs the risk of becoming dysfunctional and, thus, more likely to destroy than to create value (Barner-Rasmussen et al., 2010; Goold and Campbell, 2002). According to the work of Gnyawali et al. (2016), HQ lacks adequate analytical capabilities. More specifically, when HQ lacks knowledge about the innovation activities taking place at subsidiaries in its local networks, it is not capable of understanding the contradictions and dualities that hamper the existence of a coopetitive context.

A potential solution to this problem is for HQ to become embedded in the subsidiaries’ network to become more involved in subsidiary matters (Nell and Ambos, 2013). When HQ becomes embedded, or at least selectively locally embedded (Yamin and Forsgren, 2006), by developing its own knowledge through gathering and processing information about important local actors in the subsidiary network, HQ then has the opportunity to add value to subsidiaries’ activities (Goold et al., 1994; Nell and Ambos, 2013). Vahlne et al. (2012) advocate similar actions to overcome the liability of outsidership. To become embedded in the subsidiaries’ local networks, HQ needs to possess managerial capabilities (Gnyawali et al., 2016) and domain expertise (Nell and Ambos, 2013). As an additional – and likely insurmountable – challenge, HQ needs to reach local embeddedness in the networks of all subsidiaries that are part of the innovation activities (Birkinshaw et al., 2001; Goold et al., 1998). Research has thus indicated that such knowledge “is elusive and might be gained only through costly mechanisms,” and that “headquarters appear to experience substantial problems when attempting to add value to embedded subsidiaries” (Nell and Ambos, 2013, p. 1099). Furthermore, HQ and subsidiaries might even build overlapping relationships with the same local partners (Nell et al., 2011). Based on these hinderances, it seems naïve to assume that HQ indeed can be capable of building and managing an efficient innovation system based on coopetition without possessing and perhaps even being embedded in the subsidiaries’ local networks and thereby overcoming its lack of knowledge, sheer ignorance and liability of outsidership (Vahlne et al., 2012). However, such embeddedness can be assumed to come at a great cost for HQ.

A second challenge HQ faces when trying to organize and manage coopetition is that of subsidiaries’ strong normative expectations. As mentioned by Tsoukas (1996), understanding the MNC as a distributed knowledge system implies that subsidiaries have normative expectations associated with the role HQ is expected to play. These expectations thus constitute a demand for HQ to exercise some form of authority, coupled with socialization into the role, which in turn results in subsidiaries expecting HQ to build and manage a coopetitive innovation system. Given the existing hierarchy in the MNC, HQ might perceive strong normative expectations of subsidiaries to act despite its experienced ignorance in the form of a lack of knowledge (Ciabuschi et al., 2011b). These normative expectations might in turn lead to HQ building and managing a coopetitive innovation system despite its lack of relevant knowledge (Ciabuschi et al., 2017). In fact, HQ’s attempt to manage coopetition might even be counterproductive if it is based on such false premises in terms of the expertise HQ can contribute to the innovation activities (Ciabuschi et al., 2011a). Gnyawali et al. (2016) note that the negative consequences originating from normative expectations from subsidiaries are linked to HQ’s lack of ability to comprehend the complex interplay between competition and cooperation. Gnyawali et al. (2016) reason that a possible solution to minimize the negative impact of normative expectations is, ironically, to introduce coopetitive behavior to gain the experience needed to develop analytical and managerial capabilities at the HQ and subsidiary level.

A third challenge impeding the development and management of functioning coopetitive innovation activities within an MNC lies in the fact that HQ has its own interests and consequently acts opportunistically (Ciabuschi et al., 2017; Verbeke and Greidanus, 2012). That is, HQ makes decisions that – either consciously or as a result of ignorance – serve its own agenda rather than the greater good of the MNC as a whole (Kostova et al., 2018). Some such decisions might even have a negative impact on the subsidiaries (Hoenen and Kostova, 2015). The existence of opportunistic behavior can obviously obstruct HQ from finding a balance between ensuring competition among subsidiaries and creating a climate for cooperation. Hence, Luo’s (2005) suggestion that coordination should be managed by an executive committee at the HQ level might be problematic. Moreover, there is a constant ambivalence and balance present in MNCs related to subsidiary autonomy and HQ control (Andersson et al., 2005; Birkinshaw, 2000; McDonald et al., 2008). Indeed, innovation at subsidiaries, such as the development of new technologies, is often the result of the subsidiary taking initiative (Ambos and Schlegelmilch, 2007; Birkinshaw, 1997). Subsidiary initiatives are thus often important not only for the subsidiary but also for innovation activities in the MNC as a whole (Birkinshaw and Hood, 1998; Cantwell and Mudambi, 2005; Paterson and Brock, 2002). This also means that the subsidiaries stretch their boundaries and mandates and start questioning existing power positions and schemata within the MNC (Strutzenberger and Ambos, 2014). Therefore, HQ experiences ambivalence and challenges when trying to balance its need for control with its efforts to encourage subsidiaries to take initiative as a means to improve the MNC’s innovation performance (Ambos and Mahnke, 2010; Andersson et al., 2005; Becker-Ritterspach and Dörrenbächer, 2011). One response from HQ is to become more locally involved and thereby regain impact and control, but that might come at the expense of increased reporting and coordination (Birkinshaw et al., 2007; Ciabuschi et al., 2011a), which in turn might compromise the crucial subsidiary innovativeness in the MNC. Tippmann et al. (2018) offers a possible solution for these negative impacts, arguing that subsidiaries might apply different competitive or cooperative frames; for HQ, this means that it must first understand when the various subsidiaries employ a given frame or when they change from one frame to the other, creating a comparative pivot. Hence, HQ needs to possess both analytical capabilities and managerial capabilities to handle the subsidiaries’ frames (Gnyawali et al., 2016).

Fourth, due to experienced sheer ignorance, HQ underestimates the resources and time required for innovation activities as well as the risks involved in implementing local innovations and/or overestimating the potential benefits derived from HQ’s intervention (Ciabuschi et al., 2017). Again, these risks are likely to make the creation and management of coopetitive innovation activities within the MNC difficult, if not impossible. Vahlne et al. (2012) discuss how HQ can overcome the experienced liability of outsidership toward its subsidiaries’ local networks, offering potential solutions to avoid false estimations from HQ. For example, for HQ to learn about subsidiaries’ activities and local networks, it must interact with key subsidiary actors (Andersson et al., 2002; Mudambi and Navarra, 2004); thus, HQ needs to build a commitment to the subsidiaries. Such commitment building can take the form of HQ investing in subsidiaries’ innovation activities and subsidiaries engaging in knowledge transfer or implementing the overall corporate strategy (Boscari et al., 2016; Vahlne et al., 2012). Moreover, HQ functions could be further distributed to the subsidiaries, such as units with special roles for coordination efforts. A deepened engagement and development of closer relationships with a few selected subsidiaries that are particularly engaged in innovative activities might reduce HQ’s ignorance toward these subsidiaries, but it still remains in relation to other subsidiaries and their possible use of the innovation (Birkinshaw et al., 2000; Ciabuschi et al., 2017; Dörrenbächer and Gammelgaard, 2006).

4. Conclusion

This conceptual paper aims to contribute to the discussion on how HQ can manage the existing coopetition paradox to ensure innovation within MNCs. Although many innovation activities are planned and monitored by HQ, other innovation activities occur on a more voluntary basis between the subsidiaries and are often the result of interactions in their networks. Knowledge about these activities and networks is vital; however, as highlighted in the paper, HQ suffers from sheer ignorance, which increases the complexity involved in managing the innovation process of coopetition. Hence, the paper has argued that HQ needs to solve the coopetition paradox under the sway of a parenting paradox. Drawing on the literature on MNCs’ innovation processes, we revisited the previously suggested measures for HQ to manage coopetition among its subsidiaries with a more nuanced understanding of the role of HQ in innovation activities.

We identified four challenges as HQ faces a parenting paradox that hinders it from solving the coopetition paradox:

  1. context specificity of subsidiaries’ innovation work;

  2. normative expectations of subsidiary managers;

  3. potential opportunistic behavior of HQ; and

  4. HQ underestimation of needed resources.

We also discussed potential solutions offered in the previous literature to minimize the effect of the parenting paradox and thus enable HQ to use various measures to develop and manage a coopetitive environment within the MNC (Luo, 2005; Tippmann et al., 2018). Most of these solutions advocate that HQ needs to become more embedded in its subsidiaries’ local networks, thereby overcoming the liability of outsidership (Vahlne et al., 2012) and reducing the negative effects of strong normative expectations (Ciabuschi et al., 2017). However, as being involved in various subsidiary networks is extremely costly, HQ needs to be selective in deciding in which innovation activities to participate. To reduce the negative impact on innovation of HQ managers’ self-interests, we also suggest that coopetition should not be managed solely at the HQ level. Rather, in line with Tippmann et al. (2018), we argue that HQ should facilitate a context conducive to enabling coopetition among its subsidiaries, which can be done through a new configuration of subsidiary roles and potentially a more optimal design of MNC activities.

It is also important for HQ to recognize the implications of subsidiary coopetition for the wider organization (Tippmann et al., 2018). Although HQ largely sets the agenda for competitive and collaborative relationships within the MNC, subsidiaries have their own agendas as well. Hence, given the identified difficulties HQ faces in designing an adequate structure and processes for managing coopetition, there is a risk that those subsidiaries with a coopetition competence will act opportunistically (Tippmann et al., 2018), thereby also increasing the impact of the parenting paradox (Ciabuschi et al., 2017). A vicious cycle might result, which may explain why we have so little empirical evidence of well-functioning coopetition setups in MNC research, even though designing such a solution theoretically should offer a competitive advantage and seems achievable.

To be able to break this vicious cycle, Gnyawali et al. (2016) argue that HQ needs to build adequate analytical and managerial capabilities. In other words, HQ needs to understand and even embrace the fact that subsidiaries have different objectives for their involvement in innovation collaboration activities. To acquire necessary knowledge – and also better understand where knowledge is lacking – HQ needs to be an insider in the subsidiaries’ local networks. However, to be involved in a large number of networks comes with high costs; thus, we argue that HQ needs to prioritize and focus on those subsidiaries of high importance for innovation while also carefully ascertaining which innovation activities are of importance for more than one or a few subsidiaries. Finally, HQ efforts to lower the negative impact of the parental paradox must constitute a continuous and never-ending process, as only such ongoing experience can give HQ the ability to comprehend the complex interplay between competition and cooperation.

5. Managerial implications and future research

In this conceptual paper, we have contributed to the literature on coopetition management in MNCs by not only highlighting the role of HQ but also applying a sheer ignorance perspective, which we believe is a more realistic view on what can and cannot be managed by HQ in striving to create a coopetitive climate among subsidiaries. Our discussion can help managers better understand the complexities related to the management of coopetition in MNCs, particularly the importance and challenges of being involved in subsidiary networks. However, even though there are large costs associated with being embedded in subsidiary networks, and the results are not always immediately evident from an HQ or a subsidiary perspective, we still recommend that HQ should choose to engage in some collaborations at selected subsidiaries performing innovation activities that are likely to be of value to the MNC as a whole. HQ’s involvement in those networks can reduce the problem of sheer ignorance, enable HQ to make more informed decisions and increase the opportunities to manage innovation processes effectively. We believe that HQ managers have much to learn from re-thinking and re-evaluating their role in relation to the design and management of coopetition for innovation activities in MNCs.

As our arguments are purely conceptual due to the lack of available empirical data, we urge future researchers to add rich empirical cases and evidence from a variety of MNCs that aim to use the benefits of coopetition among their subsidiaries to foster innovation. Such evidence should preferably come from MNCs with differing organizational design solutions and in different international settings. It is also important to capture both HQ and subsidiary perspectives; hence, we recommend that, in addition to interviews with HQ, subsidiaries of high importance for innovation activities in the MNC should be interviewed. It will be of particular interest to identify how these innovation processes develop and to what extent they are influenced by HQ, other subsidiaries and relationships in the subsidiary’s local network.

References

Adenfelt, M. and Lagerström, K. (2006), “Knowledge development and sharing in multinational corporations: the case of a Centre of excellence and a transnational team”, International Business Review, Vol. 15 No. 4, pp. 381-400.

Ambos, B. and Mahnke, V. (2010), “How do MNC headquarters add value?”, Management International Review, Vol. 50 No. 4, pp. 403-412.

Ambos, B. and Schlegelmilch, B. (2007), “Innovation and control in the multinational firm: a comparison of political and contingency approaches”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 28 No. 5, pp. 473-486.

Andersson, U., Björkman, I. and Forsgren, M. (2005), “Managing subsidiary knowledge creation: the effect of control mechanisms on subsidiary local embeddedness”, International Business Review, Vol. 14 No. 5, pp. 521-538.

Andersson, U., Forsgren, M. and Holm, U. (2002), “The strategic impact of external networks: subsidiary performance and competence development in the multinational corporation”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 23 No. 11, pp. 979-996.

Andersson, U., Forsgren, M. and Holm, U. (2007), “Balancing subsidiary influence in the federative MNC: a business network view”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 38 No. 5, pp. 802-818.

Asakawa, K. (2001), “Organizational tension in international R&D management: the case of japanese firms”, Research Policy, Vol. 30 No. 5, pp. 735-757.

Asmussen, C.G., Pedersen, T. and Dhanaraj, C. (2009), “Host-country environment and subsidiary competence: extending the diamond network model”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 40 No. 1, pp. 42-57.

Barner-Rasmussen, W., Piekkari, R., Scott-Kennel, J. and Welch, C. (2010), “Commander-in-chief or absentee landlord? Key perspectives on headquarters in multinational corporations”, in Andersson U. and Holm, U. (Eds), Managing the Contemporary Multinational – The Role of Headquaters, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp. 85-105.

Becker-Ritterspach, F. and Dörrenbächer, C. (2011), “An organizational politics perspective on intra-firm competition in multinational corporations”, Management International Review, Vol. 51 No. 4, pp. 533-559.

Bengtsson, M. and Kock, S. (2000), “Coopetition’ in business networks – to cooperate and compete simultaneously”, Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 29 No. 5, pp. 411-426.

Bengtsson, M. and Kock, S. (2014), “Coopetition—quo vadis? Past accomplishments and future challenges”, Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 43 No. 2, pp. 180-188.

Birkinshaw, J. (1997), “Entrepreneurship in multinational corporations: the characteristics of subsidiary initiatives”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 18 No. 3, pp. 207-229.

Birkinshaw, J. (2000), Entrepreneurship in the Global Firm: enterprise and Renewal, Sage, London.

Birkinshaw, J. and Hood, N. (1998), “Multinational subsidiary evolution: capability and charter change in foreign-owned subsidiary companies”, The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 23 No. 4, pp. 773-795.

Birkinshaw, J.M. and Morrison, A.J. (1995), “Configurations of strategy and structure in subsidiaries of multinational corporations”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 26 No. 4, pp. 729-753.

Birkinshaw, J., Bessant, J. and Delbridge, R. (2007), “Finding, forming, and performing: creating networks for discontinuous innovation”, California Management Review, Vol. 49 No. 3, pp. 67-84.

Birkinshaw, J., Toulan, O. and Arnold, D. (2001), “Global account management in multinational corporations: Theory and evidence”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 32 No. 2, pp. 231-248.

Birkinshaw, J., Holm, U., Thilenius, P. and Arvidsson, N. (2000), “Consequences of perception gaps in the headquarters–subsidiary relationship”, International Business Review, Vol. 9 No. 3, pp. 321-344.

Boscari, S., Danese, P. and Romano, P. (2016), “Implementation of lean production in multinational corporations: a case study of the transfer process from headquarters to subsidiaries”, International Journal of Production Economics, Vol. 176, pp. 53-68.

Bouquet, C., Morrison, A. and Birkinshaw, J. (2009), “International attention and multinational enterprise performance”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 40 No. 1, pp. 108-131.

Cantwell, J. and Mudambi, R. (2005), “MNE competence‐creating subsidiary mandate”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 26 No. 12, pp. 1109-1128.

Cerrato, D. (2006), “The multinational enterprise as an internal market system”, International Business Review, Vol. 15 No. 3, pp. 253-277.

Ciabuschi, F., Dellestrand, H. and Holm, U. (2012), “The role of headquarters in the contemporary MNC”, Journal of International Management, Vol. 18 No. 3, pp. 213-223.

Ciabuschi, F., Dellestrand, H. and Kappen, P. (2011a), “Exploring the effects of vertical and lateral mechanisms in international knowledge transfer projects”, Management International Review, Vol. 51 No. 2, pp. 129-155.

Ciabuschi, F., Dellestrand, H. and Nilsson, A.C. (2015), “Value generation in the multinational corporation”, in van Tulder, R., Verbeke, A. and Drogendijk, R. (Eds), The Future of Global Organizing, Emerald Group Publishing Limited, Vol. 10, pp. 39-56.

Ciabuschi, F., Forsgren, M. and Martín, O.M. (2011b), “Rationality vs ignorance: the role of MNE headquarters in subsidiaries’ innovation processes”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 42 No. 7, pp. 958-970.

Ciabuschi, F., Forsgren, M. and Martín Martín, O. (2015), “Rationality vs ignorance: the role of MNE headquarters in subsidiaries’ innovation processes”, in Forsgren, M., Holm, U. and Johanson, J. (Eds), Knowledge, Networks and Power —The Uppsala School of International Business, Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp. 264-283.

Ciabuschi, F., Forsgren, M. and Martín Martín, O. (2017), “Value creation at the subsidiary level: testing the MNC headquarters parenting advantage logic”, Long Range Planning, Vol. 50 No. 1, pp. 48-62.

Ciabuschi, F., Holm, U. and Martín, O.M. (2014), “Dual embeddedness, influence and performance of innovating subsidiaries in the multinational corporation”, International Business Review, Vol. 23 No. 5, pp. 897-909.

Cohen, W.M. and Levinthal, D.A. (1990), “Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation”, Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 35 No. 1, pp. 128-152.

Collis, D., Young, D. and Goold, M. (2007), “The size, structure, and performance of corporate headquarters”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 28 No. 4, pp. 383-405.

Cuervo-Cazurra, A. and Narula, R. (2015), “A set of motives to unite them all? Revisiting the principles and typology of MNE motives”, The Multinational Business Review, Vol. 23 No. 1, pp. 2-14.

Dellestrand, H. (2011), “Subsidiary embeddedness as a determinant of divisional headquarters involvement in innovation transfer processes”, Journal of International Management, Vol. 17 No. 3, pp. 229-242.

Denrell, J., Arvidsson, N. and Zander, U. (2004), “Managing knowledge in the dark: an empirical study of the reliability of capability evaluations”, Management Science, Vol. 50 No. 11, pp. 1491-1503.

Dyer, J.H. and Singh, H. (1998), “The relational view: cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage”, The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 23 No. 4, pp. 660-679.

Dörrenbächer, C. and Gammelgaard, J. (2006), “Subsidiary role development: the effect of micro-political headquarters–subsidiary negotiations on the product, market and value-added scope of foreign-owned subsidiaries”, Journal of International Management, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 266-283.

Egelhoff, W.G. (2010), “How the parent headquarters adds value to an MNC”, Management International Review, Vol. 50 No. 4, pp. 413-431.

Ferraris, A. (2014), “Rethinking the literature on ‘multiple embeddedness’ and subsidiary-specific advantages”, Multinational Business Review, Vol. 22 No. 1, pp. 15-33.

Forsgren, M. and Holm, U. (2010), “MNC headquarters’ role in subsidiaries’ value-creating activities: a problem of rationality or radical uncertainty”, Scandinavian Journal of Management, Vol. 26 No. 4, pp. 421-430.

Foss, N.J. (1997), “On the rationales of corporate headquarters”, Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 6 No. 2, pp. 313-338.

Gammelgaard, J. (2009), “Issue selling and bargaining power in intrafirm competition: the differentiating impact of the subsidiary management composition”, Competition and Change, Vol. 13 No. 3, pp. 214-228.

Ghoshal, S. and Bartlett, C.A. (1990), “The multinational corporation as an interorganizational network”, The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 15 No. 4, pp. 603-626.

Gnyawali, D.R. and Park, B.R. (2011), “Co-opetition between giants: collaboration with competitors for technological innovation”, Research Policy, Vol. 40 No. 5, pp. 650-663.

Gnyawali, D.R., Madhavan, R., He, J. and Bengtsson, M. (2016), “The competition–cooperation paradox in inter-firm relationships: a conceptual framework”, Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 53, pp. 7-18.

Goold, M. and Campbell, A. (2002), “Parenting in complex structures”, Long Range Planning, Vol. 35 No. 3, pp. 219-243.

Goold, M., Campbell, A. and Alexander, M. (1994), “How corporate parents add value to the stand‐alone performance of their businesses”, Business Strategy Review, Vol. 5 No. 4, pp. 33-56.

Goold, M., Campbell, A. and Alexander, M. (1998), “Corporate strategy and parenting theory”, Long Range Planning, Vol. 31 No. 2, pp. 308-314.

Grant, R.M. (1996), “Toward a knowledge‐based theory of the firm”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 17 No. S2, pp. 109-122.

Hamel, G. (1991), “Competition for competence and interpartner learning within international strategic alliances”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 12 No. S1, pp. 83-103.

Hoenen, A.K. and Kostova, T. (2015), “Utilizing the broader agency perspective for studying headquarters–subsidiary relations in multinational companies”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 46 No. 1, pp. 104-113.

Hong, J.F. and Snell, R.S. (2015), “Knowledge development through co-opetition: a case study of a japanese foreign subsidiary and its local suppliers”, Journal of World Business, Vol. 50 No. 4, pp. 769-780.

Khanna, T., Gulati, R. and Nohria, N. (1998), “The dynamics of learning alliances: competition, cooperation, and relative scope”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 193-210.

Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1992), “Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology”, Organization Science, Vol. 3 No. 3, pp. 383-397.

Kogut, B. and Zander, U. (1996), “What firms do? Coordination, identity, and learning”, Organization Science, Vol. 7 No. 5, pp. 502-518.

Kostova, T., Nell, P.C. and Hoenen, A.K. (2018), “Understanding agency problems in headquarters-subsidiary relationships in multinational corporations: a contextualized model”, Journal of Management, Vol. 44 No. 7, pp. 2611-2637.

Lagerström, K., Schweizer, R. and Jakobsson, J. (2019), “Building R&D capability in subsidiaries – conceptualization of a process perspective”, Multinational Business Review, Vol. 27 No. 1, pp. 35-53.

Lagerström, K., Leite, E., Pahlberg, C. and Schweizer, R. (2021), “Cooperating while competing in multinational corporations”, in Arora-Jonsson, S., Brunsson, N., Hasse, R. and Lagerström, K. (Eds.) Competition: What It is and Why It Happens, Oxford University Press, pp. 176-188.

Lagerström, K., Leite, E., Pahlberg, C. and Schweizer, R. (2023), “The competition-cooperation interplay for knowledge development: a headquarters-subsidiary perspective”, Journal of Strategy and Management, Vol. 16 No. 2, pp. 362-377.

Lavie, D. (2007), “Alliance portfolios and firm performance: a study of value creation and appropriation in the US software industry”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 28 No. 12, pp. 1187-1212.

Luo, Y. (2005), “Toward coopetition within a multinational enterprise: a perspective from foreign subsidiaries”, Journal of World Business, Vol. 40 No. 1, pp. 71-90.

Luo, Y. (2007), “A coopetition perspective of global competition”, Journal of World Business, Vol. 42 No. 2, pp. 129-144.

Luo, X., Slotegraaf, R.J. and Pan, X. (2006), “Cross-functional ‘coopetition’: the simultaneous role of cooperation and competition within firms”, Journal of Marketing, Vol. 70 No. 2, pp. 67-80.

McDonald, F., Warhurst, S. and Allen, M. (2008), “Autonomy, embeddedness, and the performance of foreign owned subsidiaries”, Multinational Business Review, Vol. 16 No. 3, pp. 73-92.

Madhok, A. (1996), “Crossroads—the organization of economic activity: transaction costs, firm capabilities, and the nature of governance”, Organization Science, Vol. 7 No. 5, pp. 577-590.

Martinez, J.I. and Jarillo, J.C. (1989), “The evolution of research on coordination mechanisms in multinational corporations”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 20 No. 3, pp. 489-514.

Mudambi, R. and Navarra, P. (2004), “Is knowledge power? Knowledge flows, subsidiary power and rent-seeking within MNCs”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 35 No. 5, pp. 385-406.

Nell, P.C. and Ambos, B. (2013), “Parenting advantage in the MNC: an embeddedness perspective on the value added by headquarters”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 34 No. 9, pp. 1086-1103.

Nell, P.C., Ambos, B. and Schlegelmilch, B.B. (2011), “The MNC as an externally embedded organization: an investigation of embeddedness overlap in local subsidiary networks”, Journal of World Business, Vol. 46 No. 4, pp. 497-505.

Oliver, A.L. (2004), “On the duality of competition and collaboration: network-based knowledge relations in the biotechnology industry”, Scandinavian Journal of Management, Vol. 20 Nos 1/2, pp. 151-171.

O'Riordan, N., Ryan, P. and Andersson, U. (2023), “The subsidiary strategising process for a competence-creating role”, Multinational Business Review.

Paterson, S.L. and Brock, D.M. (2002), “The development of subsidiary-management research: review and theoretical analysis”, International Business Review, Vol. 11 No. 2, pp. 139-163.

Phene, A. and Almeida, P. (2008), “Innovation in multinational subsidiaries: the role of knowledge assimilation and subsidiary capabilities”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 39 No. 5, pp. 901-919.

Poppo, L. (2003), “The visible hands of hierarchy within the M‐form: an empirical test of corporate parenting of internal product exchanges”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 40 No. 2, pp. 403-430.

Rabbiosi, L. and Santangelo, G.D. (2013), “Parent company benefits from reverse knowledge transfer: the role of the liability of newness in MNEs”, Journal of World Business, Vol. 48 No. 1, pp. 160-170.

Raza-Ullah, T., Bengtsson, M. and Kock, S. (2014), “The coopetition paradox and tension in coopetition at multiple levels”, Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 43 No. 2, pp. 189-198.

Reilly, M., Scott, P.S., Tippmann, E. and Mangematin, V. (2023), “Sustaining competence creation in the multinational enterprise: the role of piloting in subsidiaries”, Journal of International Management, Vol. 29 No. 3, p. 101034.

Ritala, P. and Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, P. (2009), “What's in it for me? Creating and appropriating value in innovation-related coopetition”, Technovation, Vol. 29 No. 12, pp. 819-828.

Schleimer, S.C. and Pedersen, T. (2014), “The effects of MNC parent effort and social structure on subsidiary absorptive capacity”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 45 No. 3, pp. 303-320.

Strutzenberger, A. and Ambos, T.C. (2014), “Unravelling the subsidiary initiative process: a multilevel approach”, International Journal of Management Reviews, Vol. 16 No. 3, pp. 314-339.

Su, C., Kong, L., Ciabuschi, F. and Yan, H. (2021), “Reverse innovation transfer in chinese MNCs: the role of political ties and headquarters”, Journal of International Management, Vol. 27 No. 1, pp. 1-17.

Tippmann, E., Scott, P.S., Reilly, M. and O’Brien, D. (2018), “Subsidiary coopetition competence: navigating subsidiary evolution in the multinational corporation”, Journal of World Business, Vol. 53 No. 4, pp. 540-554.

Tsai, W. (2002), “Social structure of ‘coopetition’ within a multiunit organization: coordination, competition, and intraorganizational knowledge sharing”, Organization Science, Vol. 13 No. 2, pp. 179-190.

Tsai, W. and Ghoshal, S. (1998), “Social capital and value creation: the role of intrafirm networks”, Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 41 No. 4, pp. 464-476.

Tsoukas, H. (1996), “The firm as a distributed knowledge system: a constructionist approach”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 17 No. S2, pp. 11-25.

Vahlne, J.E., Schweizer, R. and Johanson, J. (2012), “Overcoming the liability of outsidership—the challenge of HQ of the global firm”, Journal of International Management, Vol. 18 No. 3, pp. 224-232.

Van den Bosch, F.A., Volberda, H.W. and De Boer, M. (1999), “Coevolution of firm absorptive capacity and knowledge environment: Organizational forms and combinative capabilities”, Organization Science, Vol. 10 No. 5, pp. 551-568.

Verbeke, A. and Greidanus, N. (2012), “The end of the opportunism versus trust debate: bounded reliability as a new envelope concept in research on MNE governance”, Handbook of Research on International Strategic Management, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp. 31-63.

Yamin, M. and Forsgren, M. (2006), “Hymer’s analysis of the multinational organization: power retention and the demise of the federative MNE”, International Business Review, Vol. 15 No. 2, pp. 166-179.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank the anonymous reviewers and the journal editor for helpful comments. Authors would also like to acknowledge the financial support from Svenska Handelsbankens Forskningsstiftelse (project number: P18:0178).

Svenska Handelsbankens Forskningsstiftelse: P18:0178.

Corresponding author

Katarina Lagerström can be contacted at: katarina.lagerstrom@fek.uu.se

About the authors

Roger Schweizer works as a Professor at the Department of Business Administration, School of Business, Economics and Law, University of Gothenburg. His present research interests are international strategy issues in general and firms’ internationalization processes, international entrepreneurship, the relationship between headquarters and subsidiaries, as well as mergers and acquisitions in particular.

Katarina Lagerström, is a Professor in International Business at the Department of Business Studies, Uppsala University, Sweden, and Associated Researcher at the School of Business, Economics and Law, Gothenburg University, Sweden. Her research interests include the internationalization process of firms and international management, with a specific focus on headquarter–subsidiary relationship in multinational firm.

Emilene Leite is a Senior Lecturer at Örebro University School of Business and active within the sectors for International Business and Marketing. Her research interests include business relationships in an international context as well as firms’ collaboration with government and civil society, i.e. non-business actors. She is particularly interested in understanding the interplay between cooperation and competition within multinationals.

Cecilia Pahlberg is a Professor at the Department of Business Studies, Uppsala University. She conducts research within the areas of international business and marketing, especially on topics related to internationalization processes, headquarters–subsidiary relationships, knowledge, influence and cultural differences within business networks consisting of business and non-business actors.

Related articles