The corporate governance lifecycle in emerging markets – the case of the Republic of Korea

Bridget McNally (School of Business, Maynooth University, Maynooth, Ireland)
Thomas O’Connor (School of Business, Maynooth University, Maynooth, Ireland)

Corporate Governance

ISSN: 1472-0701

Article publication date: 8 February 2023

Issue publication date: 29 June 2023

1070

Abstract

Purpose

This paper aims to examine the impact of the corporate lifecycle on the corporate governance practices of firms in the Republic of Korea.

Design/methodology/approach

The authors use five corporate lifecycle measures and corporate governance scores from Black et al. (2012) to estimate governance-prediction models inclusive of corporate lifecycles measures for a sample of 497 Republic of Korea firms over the 1998–2004 period.

Findings

The authors find little evidence which points to a corporate governance lifecycle for firms in the Republic of Korea. The findings suggest that factors other than firm lifecycle best explain the corporate governance practices of firms in Korea.

Originality/value

Using a battery of lifecycle measures and corporate governance indexes and subindexes, the authors believe this paper represents the most rigorous study yet to study the corporate governance lifecycle in an emerging market economy, namely, the Republic of Korea.

Keywords

Citation

McNally, B. and O’Connor, T. (2023), "The corporate governance lifecycle in emerging markets – the case of the Republic of Korea", Corporate Governance, Vol. 23 No. 5, pp. 1046-1062. https://doi.org/10.1108/CG-10-2022-0422

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2022, Bridget McNally and Thomas O’Connor.

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial & non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

Corporate governance–lifecycle theory considers a relationship between corporate governance and the corporate lifecycle stage and suggests that corporate governance can manifest itself in different roles across the corporate lifecycle. Filatotchev et al. (2006) show that the relative importance of the three main functions of corporate governance, namely, monitoring, resource and strategy, varies across the firm lifecycle. The resource and strategic roles of governance are prominent in early- and growth-stage firms, where resources are low and governance is required to “fuel and support growth.” Corporate governance–lifecycle theory posits that the board of directors advises (in early-stage firms) and monitors (in mature-stage firms). For example, in high-tech firms, board members benefit the firm with knowledge, reputation, social capital and networking (Bertone et al., 2013). For listed firms in Australia, Habib et al. (2018) show that advisory (monitoring) directors are more in demand in the early (mature) lifecycle stages. In growth/mature-stage firms, investment in accountability/transparency widens the firm’s access to a larger pool of resources once it transitions from private to public firm, allowing the firm to fund its growth opportunities. Transparency declines in mature-stage firms once growth opportunities have been exhausted. These findings suggest there is a corporate governance “mix” best suited to each lifecycle stage.

Corporate governance standards in emerging markets have progressed substantially in recent decades (Claessens and Yurtoglu, 2013). For example, in the aftermath of the Asian financial crisis, the Republic of Korea mandated internal and external corporate governance reforms, which together with governance reforms adopted voluntarily by Korean firms, resulted in major restructuring among Korean firms, for example, large public firms were required to have at least 50% outside independent directors (Kim and Kim, 2008). Between 1998 and 2004, the Korean Corporate Governance Index for large firms rose from 30.78 to 69.64 (out of 100) (Black et al., 2006). However, what is not clear from the literature to date is the nature of the adoption of corporate governance by Republic of Korea firms. The corporate governance lifecycle model says that for governance adoption to be optimal, firms must recognize that the net benefits of individual corporate governance attributes are not uniformly the same across the firm lifecycle. An alternate “one size fits all” approach says that firms can ignore the firm lifecycle and apply the same corporate governance practices regardless of their own stage of development [1]. In this paper, we examine whether the adoption of better governance standards by firms in the Republic of Korea follow the predictions of the corporate governance lifecycle or can be more readily aligned with the “one size fits all” approach.

Robust evidence in support of the corporate governancelifecycle model has been found in developed countries. Loderer et al. (2012) conclude that governance quality in US firms tends to deteriorate as firms age. In Australia, Habib et al. (2018) show that advisory (monitoring) directors are more in demand in early (mature) lifecycle stages. In contrast, the evidence to date does not suggest that emerging market firms have embraced the corporate governance–lifecycle model. Esqueda and O’Connor (2020), hereafter, EOC (2020), examined the impact of the corporate lifecycle on corporate governance in Brazil and whether listing-level decisions are a better indicator of corporate governance quality than corporate lifecycle. They find little evidence to support a corporate governance–lifecycle relationship; instead, firms match their corporate governance practices with their exchange listing (i.e. the bonding or self-selection view), independently of lifecycle requirements [2]. O’Connor and Byrne (2013), hereafter, OCB (2013), also study the corporate governance lifecycle in emerging economies. However, their findings are inconclusive because of concerns about the corporate governance data and the lifecycle measures they used. This raises the question of whether the evolution of corporate governance in entities of emerging economies is captured by the lifecycle model. The findings of EOC (2020) also suggest the need for further research as to whether the lack of evidence of a corporate governance–lifecycle relationship overall, masked the reality of a relationship between individual corporate governance attributes and lifecycle stages – in other words, whether, in an equally weighted index, the number of attributes with relationships with lifecycle may be canceled out by attributes not displaying relationships [3].

In this paper, we undertake what we believe to be the most comprehensive analysis of the corporate governance lifecycle in an emerging market economy [4]. Our study differs from EOC (2020) and OCB (2013) in a number of important respects. First, EOC (2020) study the corporate governance lifecycle in Brazil. In this paper, we choose to study the corporate governance lifecycle in the Republic of Korea. Choosing the Republic of Korea allows us to study the corporate governance lifecycle using a larger sample of firms and over a longer time period. EOC (2020) examine a panel of 116 firms over three years resulting in a total sample of 180 firm-year observations. In this study, we use a sample of 497 individual firms or 2,185 firm-year observations in total. Second, we use an extensive set of lifecycle indicators, including firm age, to test for the corporate governance lifecycle. Recent work suggests lifecycle proxies can conflict with one another (Von Eije and Megginson, 2008; Banyi and Kahle, 2014), implying that reliance on a single lifecycle proxy is potentially problematic. Banyi and Kahle (2014) show that firm age and not categorical lifecycle indicators (e.g. retained earnings to total equity [RETE] lifecycle) do a better job of capturing lifecycle dynamics. OCB (2013) do not identify specific lifecycle stages, which makes it difficult to interpret their findings. Third, we test for the corporate governance lifecycle in individual corporate governance attributes so that we can rule out the possibility that aggregation of individual governance attributes into an overall governance score or subindex masks important lifecycle effects.

Our analysis shows that corporate governance practices improved in Korea during the period under review but there is little evidence to support a lifecycle model of corporate governance. Beyond the introduction stage, firms in Korea change their corporate governance practices little as they mature. Instead, firms in Korea appear to practice a “one size fits all” governance model, which combines elements of good board practices, shareholder rights and to a lesser extent, disclosures. Factors other than lifecycle, like firm size, explain cross-sectional differences in corporate governance practices.

Our paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the lifecycle measures we apply in this study. Section 3 describes the sample. Sections 4–7 set out our findings and estimate governance–lifecycle models. Section 8 concludes.

2. Identifying corporate lifecycles

In this study, we use five lifecycle proxy measures: the RETE measure of DeAngelo et al. (2006); the multistage lifecycle approaches of each of Dickinson et al. (2011), Faff et al. (2016) and AR (1992), and finally, firm age. First, following DeAngelo et al. (2006), we use the ratio of RETE, where total equity is the sum of retained and contributed equity. The premise underlying RETE as a lifecycle measure is that RETE increases as firms mature; young firms with little or no retained equity and reliance on contributed (external) equity have low RETE ratios, whereas mature firms with a diminishing investment opportunity set have greater access to internal funds (retained equity) and less need for contributed equity. Although intuitively appealing, the use of RETE as a lifecycle indicator is not without its problems. First, and like other univariate lifecycle measures, RETE cannot truly classify firms into different lifecycle stages. Second, Bhattacharya et al. (2020) highlight that RETE fails to capture the nonlinear relationship that exists between lifecycle stages and dividend payout [5].

Bhattacharya et al. (2020) show that Dickinson (2011) and not RETE lifecycle does a better job in capturing the nonlinear lifecycle stage hypothesis. Dickinson (2011), a multistage lifecycle model, classifies firms into one of five lifecycle stages, namely, introduction/birth, growth, maturity, shake-out and decline based on the combined signs of net cash flows from operating, financing and investing activities. Net cash flows can be positive or negative, resulting in eight possible cash flow combinations. We follow Faff et al. (2016) in combining the shake-out and decline stages. While superior to other multistage lifecycle measures, the Dickinson (2011) lifecycle measure is itself subject to some limitations. First, it is the sign and not the magnitude of the net cash flows which is used to assign firm years to a lifecycle stage. Dickinson (2011) treats net cash flows of different magnitude, but of the same sign, equally. Second, cash flows can suffer from issues relating to timing and matching and can also be managed, to the extent that lifecycles determined by the sign of net cash flows may be misclassified.

Faff et al. (2016) advocates using multiclass linear discriminant analysis (MLDA) to assign annual firm-years to lifecycle stages and provide several arguments as to why MLDA is a superior lifecycle classification system. We use MLDA to classify firms into one of four lifecycle stages. This approach initially follows Dickinson (2011) to allocate firms to a lifecycle stage but then refines the classification by performing linear discriminant analysis, such as Groupi=α0+α1AGEi+α2PROFITi+α3SGrowthi+εi, where age is firm age, PROFIT is EBIT/assets and SGrowth is one-year sales growth. Using these variables, MLDA provides maximum separation between the groups. A benefit that MLDA and Dickinson (2011) have over RETE is that it explicitly classifies firm years to a lifecycle stage. MLDA is our preferred lifecycle indicator and is our main reference point. Faff et al. (2016) combine Dickinson (2011), firm age, sales growth, profitability and RETE to assign firm years to lifecycle stages. Because of the limitations of RETE, we use two MLDA specifications; one with and one without RETE.

We use the multistage lifecycle measure of AR (1992). It is a composite indicator based on four lifecycle descriptors, namely, dividends (ratio of common dividends to income), capital expenditures (capital expenditures to firm value), one-year sales growth and firm age. It is assumed that all four variables are monotonically related to firm maturity: increasing for dividends and firm age and decreasing for sales growth and capital expenditures. Based on this indicator, firm years are classified into one of four lifecycle stages, namely, birth stage, growth stage, mature stage and decline stage, using portfolio sorts. Because firms are assigned to a lifecycle stage annually, firms can and do gravitate across lifecycle stages over the sample period.

The last remaining lifecycle measure we use is firm age. Many papers have suggested that firm age is an imperfect lifecycle proxy. Rather than increase monotonically with maturity, the “firm age–maturity” relationship is inverted u-shaped; by definition, new firms are young in age but are also more likely to fail, meaning that young firms can occupy the introduction and decline lifecycle stages. Von Eije and Megginson (2008) suggest that firm age measures calendar age. whereas RETE captures “financial age.” In support of firm age as a lifecycle measure, Banyi and Kahle (2014) show that RETE is not a meaningful lifecycle measure for all firms.

3. Variable and sample description

We source corporate governance scores for Korea from Black et al. (2012) [6]. Their corporate governance index is an equally weighted average of five corporate governance subelements, namely, board structure, board procedure, disclosure, shareholder rights and ownership, which collectively cover 26 individual corporate governance provisions in the years 1998–2004. Corporate governance scores range from 0 to a high of 100. In all governance–lifecycle regressions, we control for a range of firm-level influences on corporate governance practices. With the exception of the chaebol indicator, which we source from Black et al. (2012), we source the data from Worldscope. We describe the independent variables in Appendix. We exclude firms in the financial and utility sectors and firms with negative total equity, missing retained equity and missing control variables. Our final sample comprises 497 individual firms with 2,185 firm-year observations in total.

4. Corporate governance quality in Korea over the sample period

Table 1 and Figure 1 plot corporate governance quality in Korea over the sample period. Figure 1 plots mean and median corporate governance, board structure, board procedure, shareholder rights and disclosure. We report also the within-firm trend in corporate governance (the blue line) to alleviate concerns that the trends we observe over time arise in part because of changes in sample composition. Overall, firms in Korea are more likely to adopt board procedures and shareholder rights provisions. In contrast, few firms choose to enhance board structure and disclosure. As per Figure 1, reforms in Korea post-Asian crisis led to improvements in corporate governance standards; governance was always higher in 2004 than in 1998. The within-firm trends suggest the changes in corporate governance are substantial and economically significant; between 1998–2004, overall corporate governance improved by 18.8%, board structure by 8.9%, board procedure by 18.8%, disclosure standards by 28.4% and shareholder rights by 39.3%.

Table 1 plots the level of adoption by firms of each of the 26 individual corporate governance provisions over time. Not all of the individual corporate governance attributes have been universally adopted. For example, the incidence of having at least four board meetings in a year increased from 36.36% in 1998 to 95.48% in 2004. In contrast, “board has an outside chair or lead director,” “compensation committee” and “cumulative voting for the election of directors” have been largely shunned by Korean firms.

5. Observing corporate governance and corporate lifecycles patterns

Having established that firms improved their corporate governance between 1998 and 2004, next we turn to the corporate governance lifecycle. Table 2 characterizes firms in each lifecycle stage. Except for AR (1992), the number of firm-year observations is the largest for mature-stage firms. With the MLDA lifecycle, as firms progress from the introduction stage to the mature stage, RETE, firm age and years-listed increase. Consistent with the lifecycle model of dividends, as firms mature, they become more profitable and rely less on external financing, allowing them to make larger dividend payouts (DeAngelo et al., 2006). As firms mature, they use more internal equity and less debt financing, which is consistent with the recent findings of Kieschnick and Moussawi (2018). Firm growth and capital expenditures are the largest in the growth stage. Overall MLDA appears to assign firms to lifecycle stages in a manner consistent with the lifecycle view of the firm.

Focusing on Dickinson (2011) and RETE, we observe similar patterns across the lifecycle. Using Dickinson (2011), both RETE and firm age increase as firms mature. Growth, profitability, CAPEX and dividend payout behave in a manner consistent with MLDA lifecycle. Once again, debt declines as firms mature. There is less agreement between each of MLDA, Dickinson (2011) and RETE with AR (1992). In the latter, RETE is maximized among early- and not mature-stage firms. Firm growth is the largest among introduction-stage firms and dividend payouts are the largest in growth-stage firms.

Figure 2 compares lifecycle measures to each other in more detail. We compare Dickinson (2011), AR (1992), RETE and firm-age with MLDA acting as the reference lifecycle measure. RETE and RETA are the largest for MLDA lifecycle mature-stage firms, whereas firm age is the largest in shake-out/decline stage firms. MLDA is more like Dickinson (2011) than AR (1992); more than half of MLDA mature-stage firm-year observations are also mature-stage observations according to Dickinson (2011). Fewer than a quarter of MLDA mature-stage observations are mature-stage firms according to AR (1992).

The middle rows of Figure 2 list the number of lifecycle stages by firm. With MLDA lifecycle, 233 firms occupy two lifecycle stages, 82 firms have three lifecycle stages and 9 firms occupy all four lifecycle stages over the sample period. With RETE, firms remain in the same lifecycle stage throughout. The bottom rows of Figure 2 depict each of the four multistage lifecycle measures for four select firms, namely, Samsung Electronics, Hyundai Motors, LG International and Korea Air Lines. For each firm, MLDA tracks Dickinson (2011) more closely compared to AR (1992) [7].

6. Estimating corporate governance prediction models for firms in Korea

In this section, we extend the analysis of Black et al. (2006) and estimate corporate governance-prediction models for firms in Korea with each lifecycle measure included as a predictor variable as follows:

(1) Corporate governanceit=β0+β1Growthstageit+β2Maturestageit+ β3Shakeout/declinestageit+Firm controlsit+ Timet+εit

The dependent variable is overall corporate governance, board structure, board procedure, disclosure, shareholder rights and ownership, as indicated in Figure 3, or each of the 26 individual corporate governance attributes in turn, as indicated in Table 3. In each regression where one of Dickinson (2011), RETE and AR (1992) are examined, the full set of firm-level control variables outlined in Section 3 and time fixed effects are included. In MLDA regressions, profitability, growth and firm age are excluded because each is used to assign firms to MLDA lifecycle stages. Each regression is estimated using pooled ordinary least squares with standard errors clustered by firm (Petersen, 2009). In the MLDA, Dickinson (2011) and AR (1992) regressions, the introduction-stage is the omitted/reference lifecycle stage. In RETE lifecycle, the young-stage is the omitted/reference lifecycle stage.

The results are presented in Figure 3. Rather than outline estimated coefficients for each lifecycle measure and each control variable, we present the predicted level of corporate governance for the average firm in each lifecycle stage. These predicted values say there is little evidence to support a lifecycle model of corporate governance in Korea. For example, using the MLDA lifecycle, there are no statistically significant differences in each of overall corporate governance, board procedure, disclosure and ownership structure across lifecycle stages. Using Dickinson (2011) and except for shareholder rights, overall governance and all other governance attributes do not change over the lifecycle [8]. Where we do observe statistically significant differences in corporate governance adoption across the firm lifecycle, the differences are economically small. For example, MLDA and Dickinson (2011) agree that shareholder rights are lowest for mature-stage firms. Using MLDA, the difference in shareholder rights between introduction- and mature-stage firms is just 2.92 percentage points. Using RETE, overall corporate governance is 1.05% or 3.05% higher for mature-stage firms when compared to the governance practices of young-stage firms.

In Table 3, we estimate corporate governance lifecycles for each of the 27 individual corporate governance attributes using MLDA and RETE. Estimating separate governance–lifecycle models for each of the individual attributes may reveal governance lifecycles not evident when the individual attributes are grouped together. Of the 27 governance attributes, MLDA and RETE together identify changes in the same ten attributes over the lifecycle, and both point to a fall in the adoption of each corporate governance attribute as firms mature. Except for “audit committee has majority of outside directors” and “audit committee includes accounting or finance expert,” both of which have few firm-year observations, most other individual governance attributes change little across the lifecycle. Also, economic significance is typically observed where governance adoption is low and small changes in the number of firms that adopt each provision result in large percentage changes in adoption across the lifecycle. For example, MLDA mature stage firms are most likely to employ a foreign outside director, yet the number of firms that employ a foreign outside director across the lifecycle is small. In a total sample of 497 firms, 14% or 69.6 mature-stage firms use foreign directors compared to 8% or 40 introduction-stage firms, resulting in a 75% increase overall. Each MLDA lifecycle stage firm is most likely to use a bylaw to govern the board of directors, and while adoption is lowest for growth-stage firms, the difference between introduction- and growth-stage firms is 30 firms (367 versus 337 firms).

7. Estimating corporate governance lifecycles using firm age

In Table 4, we estimate corporate governance–lifecycle regressions with the log of firm age as the lifecycle measure. Figure 4 presents predicted corporate governance for firms sorted by firm age with firm age ranging from 0 to 100 years of age. We observe little change in overall governance, shareholder rights and board structure as firms age. For example, the range in overall governance across firm age is just 3.37. The percentage fall in the level of broad structure is large, but only because the level of board structure practices is small overall. Ownership becomes more concentrated as firms age, yet at all ages, ownership in Korean firms is highly concentrated; the minimum level of ownership concentration across the age distribution is 84.08%. The number of firms voluntarily adopting board procedure practices fall from 207.7 for the youngest firms to 177 for the oldest firms. There is a pronounced change in disclosure practices as firms age, which we do not observe using any of the multistage lifecycle measures. The adoption of disclosure practices is low overall but falls from 20.69 for the youngest firms to just 3.21 for the oldest firms, corresponding to a decrease of 84.48% overall. The negative disclosure–age relationship we uncover for firms in Korea is inconsistent with the prediction in Filatotchev et al. (2006) which says firms become more transparent and provide fuller disclosures as they mature. However, the negative disclosure–firm age relationship is consistent with the practice by firms of building reputation (Gomes, 2000). According to the reputation-building theory, firms with abundant growth opportunities yet financially constrained, in large part because they operate in a country with weak institutions, attempt to establish a history of trust with outside investors. Firms can build trust with investors in a variety of ways. These include bonding to improved corporate governance standards, paying large dividends and making voluntary disclosures. Our results suggest that disclosure standards are weak in Korea overall during the sample period, yet young, presumably growth firms, make above-average disclosures, possibly to build reputation capital with prospective investors. As firms age and the need for external financing diminish, disclosures diminish.

8. Concluding remarks

Corporate governance–lifecycle theory considers a relationship between the evolution of corporate governance and the corporate lifecycle stage and suggests that corporate governance can manifest itself in different roles across the corporate lifecycle. The evidence to date points to a robust corporate governance lifecycle in developed market countries, but research in this area on emerging economies is less conclusive. This paper builds on the work of EOC (2020) and examines the impact of the corporate lifecycle on corporate governance in the Republic of Korea using a sample of 497 individual firms and an extensive set of lifecycle indicators. We find little evidence to support a lifecycle model of corporate governance. Our analysis suggests that while emerging market firms voluntarily adopt many governance practices of developed market firms, how they adapt governance differs from developed market firms' practices and they do not appear to choose the corporate governance practices best suited to each life cycle stage. In what we believe to be the most rigorous test to date of the corporate governance–lifecycle model in an emerging market our findings suggest that in emerging markets there is a perceived level of corporate governance necessary for firms who are establishing a reputation (early- and growth-stage firms), but the corporate governance focus plateaus once this perceived required level is achieved.

Figures

Corporate governance in Korea

Figure 1

Corporate governance in Korea

Comparing lifecycle measures

Figure 2

Comparing lifecycle measures

Estimates of the corporate governance lifecycle in Korea

Figure 3

Estimates of the corporate governance lifecycle in Korea

Predicted corporate governance and firm age in Korea

Figure 4

Predicted corporate governance and firm age in Korea

Corporate governance in the Republic of Korea

Corporate governance attribute Obs (%) Adoption Removals 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Δ(04–98)
Board structure subindex
≥ 50% outside directors 2,183 11.04 59 8 0.00 0.47 4.80 13.64 15.58 15.56 17.51 17.51***
>50% outside directors 2,183 3.11 24 1 0.00 0.00 0.53 1.77 2.92 5.28 8.19 8.19***
Board has outside chair or lead director 2,185 0.09 1 0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.56 0.56
Audit committee 2,185 15.88 72 0 0.00 0.00 12.53 17.42 23.38 21.11 23.45 23.45***
Audit committee has majority of outside directors 321 72.27 9 2 80.00 77.27 74.47 79.69 67.80 65.52 71.21 (8.79)
Compensation committee 2,185 0.96 5 0 0.00 0.00 0.53 0.76 1.62 0.83 2.26 2.26**
Outside director nominating committee 2,185 19.18 95 0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.51 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
Board procedure subindex
≥ 4 board meetings in a year 1,989 86.48 129 58 36.36 86.08 78.49 75.76 96.43 93.33 95.48 59.12***
Firm evaluates non-executive directors 2,125 7.53 32 24 2.33 3.47 4.27 2.28 7.62 5.54 6.50 4.17**
Outside directors-only annual board meeting 2,159 9.73 93 62 0.00 0.00 2.40 3.54 16.56 17.75 13.28 13.28***
Bylaw/policy to govern board 2,172 79.33 128 65 70.56 72.33 67.20 84.58 80.84 84.17 85.03 14.47***
Directors’ votes recorded in board minutes 2,054 50.10 141 126 41.81 40.98 40.80 46.46 43.18 45.61 45.42 3.61
Firm has a foreign outside director 2,185 10.39 26 16 12.15 14.69 8.80 9.60 10.06 9.44 10.73 (1.42)
Shareholders approve outside directors’ pay 1,833 27.61 15 12 1.33 2.30 10.50 9.46 9.22 8.73 11.16 9.82***
Outsider directors attend minimum % of meetings 2,068 53.92 114 94 43.05 44.69 45.17 48.34 52.27 48.06 51.13 8.08*
Bylaw to govern audit committee 2,131 76.91 187 130 68.18 67.16 65.49 83.68 71.99 82.46 75.14 6.96*
Audit committee includes accounting or finance expert 328 83.84 13 0 0.00 57.89 72.73 80.60 87.10 88.89 94.44 94.44***
Audit committee approves internal audit head 1,806 57.53 65 55 1.45 17.00 44.04 49.05 30.67 36.58 35.03 33.58***
≥ 4 audit committee meetings in a year 328 55.18 20 10 0.00 50.00 40.48 45.00 57.58 67.19 69.70 69.70***
Disclosure subindex
Firm has regular meetings with analysts 2,185 20.87 115 0 3.87 4.27 3.47 22.22 34.09 27.50 38.14 34.27***
English language financial statements exist 2,176 17.78 133 0 7.73 6.64 6.49 14.80 17.86 15.83 44.07 36.33***
Board members’ background disclosed 2,082 10.57 15 0 5.92 4.59 4.08 4.75 6.64 5.88 7.34 1.43
Shareholder rights subindex
Firm allows voting by postal ballot 2,171 6.86 31 32 2.31 5.85 7.20 9.60 5.52 7.78 6.50 4.19**
Cumulative voting for election of directors 2,176 2.90 25 14 0.00 0.97 2.40 4.55 0.97 1.94 6.78 6.78***
Director candidates disclosed to shareholders in advance of shareholder meeting 2,156 55.10 300 32 1.86 11.76 10.96 24.81 100.00 100.00 100.00 98.14***
RPTs require board approval 2,102 43.15 141 22 8.43 23.70 38.13 48.10 54.03 52.45 53.50 45.06***
Notes:

We report the evolution of corporate governance over time for overall governance, board structure, board procedure, disclosure, and shareholder rights and the elements of each governance subindex. Corporate governance scores are provided by Black et al. (2012); ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10% level, respectively

Characterizing firms by lifecycle stage

MLDA lifecycle Dickinson (2011) lifecycle
Intro Growth Mature SO/decline Range across stages Intro Growth Mature SO/decline Range across stages
Observations 475 433 762 515 205 483 861 636
RETE 0.00 0.29 0.53 0.14 0.53 0.17 0.30 0.33 0.20 0.16
RETA 0.00 0.14 0.34 0.05 0.34 0.06 0.15 0.19 0.07 0.13
Firm age 27 years 28 years 36 years 43 years 16 years 32 years 33 years 33 years 35 years 3 years
Years listed 13 years 13 years 16 years 25 years 12 years 13 years 16 years 15 years 16 years 3 years
Growth 0.07 0.20 0.07 (0.04) 0.24 0.05 0.08 0.07 0.03 0.05
Profitability (0.02) 0.04 0.06 0.01 0.08 0.01 0.03 0.04 0.02 0.03
Size decile 5 5 5 7 2 4 6 6 5 2
Dividend payout 0.000 0.008 0.011 0.002 0.011 0.002 0.006 0.009 0.003 0.007
CAPEX 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.01 0.03 0.05 0.04 0.02 0.03
EFD 0.31 (0.39) (0.75) (0.30) 1.06 2.63 0.01 (1.50) 0.17 4.13
Book debt 0.43 0.29 0.16 0.38 0.27 0.39 0.32 0.23 0.33 0.16
Cash 0.07 0.09 0.12 0.08 0.05 0.08 0.11 0.09 0.08 0.03
AR (1992) lifecycle RETE lifecycle
Intro Growth Mature Decline Range across stages Young Mature Old Range across stages
Observations 661 590 443 491 548 1,093 544
RETE 0.32 0.32 0.28 0.14 0.18 0.00 0.27 0.64 0.64
RETA 0.16 0.16 0.14 0.05 0.11 0.00 0.14 0.38 0.38
Firm age 27 years 35 years 35 years 41 years 14 years 34 years 35 years 32 years 3 years
Years listed 13 years 16 years 16 years 23 years 10 years 16 years 16 years 14 years 2 years
Growth 0.12 0.07 0.05 (0.01) 0.13 0.02 0.07 0.07 0.05
Profitability 0.04 0.04 0.03 0.01 0.03 0.00 0.03 0.07 0.07
Size decile 5 6 5 5 1 5 6 5 1
Dividend payout 0.006 0.007 0.006 0.000 0.007 0.000 0.008 0.010 0.010
CAPEX 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.04 0.03 0.02
EFD (0.20) (0.33) (0.65) (0.86) 0.66 (0.07) (0.43) (0.62) 0.55
Book debt 0.29 0.28 0.28 0.34 0.06 0.42 0.31 0.17 0.25
Cash 0.09 0.09 0.10 0.08 0.02 0.07 0.08 0.14 0.07
Note:

We compare the median firm classified by MLDA, RETE, Dickinson (2011) and AR (1992)

Estimating the corporate governance lifecycle for individual corporate governance attributes

MLDA lifecycle stages RETE lifecycle stages
Intro Growth
(a)
Mature
(b)
Decline
(c)
(b) vs (a) (c) vs (a) (c) vs (b) Young Mature
(a)
Old
(b)
(b) vs (a) Sig. in MLDA
and RETE
Board structure subindex
≥ 50% outside directors 0.13 0.11 0.08** 0.13 ** 0.13 0.10 0.10
>50% outside directors 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03
Board has outside chair or lead director 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
Audit committee 0.19 0.14** 0.15 0.15* 0.15 0.16 0.17
Audit committee has majority of outside directors 0.82 0.64** 0.60** 0.81 ** ** 0.85 0.69** 0.63** * Yes
Compensation committee 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.01
Outside director nominating committee 0.22 0.17* 0.18 0.19 0.18 0.17 0.25* *** Yes
Board structure subindex
≥ 4 board meetings in a year 0.90 0.84* 0.85 0.87 0.90 0.85*** 0.85* Yes
Firm evaluates nonexecutive directors 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03
Outside directors-only annual board meeting 0.07 0.10 0.07 0.10 0.09 0.09 0.06 *
Bylaw/policy to govern board 0.81 0.76 0.75* 0.75* 0.78 0.79 0.70** *** Yes
Directors’ votes recorded in board minutes 0.46 0.42 0.40 0.47 * 0.45 0.46 0.38 ** Yes
Firm has foreign outside director 0.08 0.12 0.14* 0.06 ** *** 0.11 0.09 0.13
Shareholders approve outside directors’ pay 0.07 0.11 0.08 0.08 0.07 0.08 0.11
Outsider directors attend minimum % of meetings 0.50 0.51 0.48 0.45 0.49 0.45 0.53 *
Bylaw to govern audit committee 0.74 0.68* 0.69 0.74 * 0.74 0.71 0.69
Audit committee includes accounting or finance expert 0.91 0.88 0.76* 0.82 * 0.95 0.78** 0.84 Yes
Audit committee approves internal audit head 0.34 0.34 0.33 0.33 0.31 0.35 0.32
≥ 4 audit committee meetings in a year 0.56 0.61 0.57 0.50 0.62 0.56 0.42*
Disclosure index
Firm has regular meetings with analysts 0.24 0.19 0.18* 0.23 * 0.19 0.23 0.19 Yes
English language financial statements exist 0.16 0.18 0.17 0.16 0.17 0.16 0.17
Board members’ background disclosed 0.04 0.05 0.07 0.04 0.03 0.06* 0.07**
Shareholder rights index
Firm allows voting by postal ballot 0.05 0.08 0.06 0.08 0.05 0.08 0.07
Cumulative voting for election of directors 0.04 0.04 0.01 0.03 * 0.00 0.04*** 0.04** Yes
Director candidates disclosed to shareholders in advance 0.55 0.56 0.52 0.55 ** 0.56 0.54 0.52** Yes
RPTs require board approval 0.47 0.45 0.37*** 0.47 ** *** 0.44 0.46 0.36* *** Yes
Notes:

This table presents predicted corporate governance adoption over the firm lifecycle from a series of pooled linear probability model regressions. In each regression, the dependent variable equals 1 if the firm adopts the individual corporate governance attribute and 0 otherwise, as indicated. Lifecycle is measured using MLDA lifecycle and RETE lifecycle, as indicated. T-stats, which are adjusted for firm-level clustering, are not reported. All regressions include a constant and time fixed effects, neither of which are reported. ***, ** and *denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10% levels, respectively

Corporate governance–lifecycle regressions using firm age

Dependent variable is Lifecycle measure is log (age)
Corporate governance (1.390)**
Board structure (1.710)***
Board procedure (1.665)*
Shareholder rights (0.896)
Disclosure (5.543)***
Ownership structure 2.343**
Board structure subindex
≥ 50% outside directors (0.082)***
>50% outside directors (0.031)
Board has outside chair or lead director (0.003)
Audit committee (0.030)
Audit committee has majority of outside directors (0.131)**
Compensation committee (0.020)**
Outside director nominating committee (0.030)
Board procedure subindex
≥ 4 board meetings in a year 0.005
Firm evaluates nonexecutive directors (0.012)
Outside directors-only annual board meeting 0.026*
Bylaw/policy to govern board 0.038
Directors’ votes recorded in board minutes (0.032)
Firm has foreign outside director (0.023)
Shareholders approve outside directors’ pay (0.020)
Outsider directors attend minimum % of meetings (0.083)**
Bylaw to govern audit committee (0.023)
Audit committee includes accounting or finance expert (0.045)
Audit committee approves internal audit head 0.011
≥ 4 audit committee meetings in a year (0.058)
Disclosure subindex
Firm has regular meetings with analysts (0.070)**
English language financial statements exist (0.061)**
Board members’ background disclosed (0.036)*
Shareholder rights subindex
Firm allows voting by postal ballot 0.031
Cumulative voting for election of directors (0.036)
Director candidates disclosed to shareholders in advance of shareholder meeting 0.000
RPTs require board approval (0.026)
Notes:

This table presents estimated coefficients from a series of pooled ordinary least squares regressions. In each regression, the dependent variable is overall corporate governance or one of its subcomponents. Lifecycle is measured using firm age. ***, ** and *denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10% levels, respectively

Independent variable descriptions and summary statistics

Variable Description Mean Median SD
Sales growth One-year growth in sales 0.08 0.06 0.25
Profitability Earnings before interest and taxation to book assets 0.02 0.03 0.10
Growth opportunities Market to the book of assets 0.64 0.43 0.67
Years listed Year’s stock exchange listed 17.55 15.00 9.28
Size Log of book assets in local currency 19.42 19.16 1.40
Size dummy Equals one if the firm is a large firm 0.10 0.00 0.30
Leverage Log of the ratio of debt to equity 0.79 0.81 1.21
PPE/Sales Property plant and equipment to sales 0.53 0.42 0.45
Cross list Equals one if the firm is cross-listed in the United States 0.04 0.00 0.20
Business Group Equals one if the firm belongs to a business group 0.33 0.00 0.47
Advertising Advertising to sales 0.01 0.00 0.020
External finance dependence CAPEX less cash flow from operations to CAPEX (2.17) (0.39) 13.48
Exports Exports to sales 0.31 0.20 0.31
CAPEX Capital expenditures to sales 0.05 0.03 0.07
Firm risk The standard deviation of weekly share prices 0.10 0.10 0.03
Market share Firm’s share of industry sales 0.07 0.01 0.16
R&D spend Research and development spend to sales 0.01 0.00 0.015
Insider ownership Ownership of shares by the largest control group 0.33 0.33 0.17
Cash Cash to sales 0.14 0.09 0.14

Notes

1.

The adoption of “across the board” rules has proven to be beneficial in some countries (Atanasov et al., 2010).

2.

Lee and Choi (2018) reveal a corporate social responsibility lifecycle model for Republic of Korea firms.

3.

Black et al. (2006) provide a comprehensive analysis of firm-level influences on the corporate governance practices of firms in the Republic of Korea. They do not examine the influence of lifecycle.

4.

Claessens and Yurtoglu (2013) define the Republic of Korea as an emerging economy.

5.

We use the multistage lifecycle version of RETE as proposed by Banyi and Kahle (2014). They classify firms into “young,” “mature” and “old” lifecycle stages by separating the RETE distribution into quartiles; firms with RETE in the bottom and top quartiles are deemed “young” and “old,” respectively, and firms are “mature” when RETE occupies the interquartile range.

6.

We thank Bernard Black for kindly providing his data to us.

7.

One concern is our multistage lifecycle measures are not robust measures of the firm lifecycle. To address this concern, we estimate lifecycle models for each of dividend payout, debt and growth opportunity. We identify distinct lifecycle models for each. Dividend payouts are the largest for mature-stage firms. Debt use falls as firms mature, presumable as firms generate more internal funds and growth opportunities fall. Changes in dividends, debt and growth opportunities across the lifecycle are economically large.

8.

Note that we also test for differences in corporate governance across lifecycle stages and find that the differences are rarely statistically significant.

Appendix

Table A1

References

Atanasov, V., Black, B., Ciccotello, C. and Gyoshev, S. (2010), “How does law affect finance? An examination of equity tunnelling in Bulgaria”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 96, pp. 155-173.

Banyi, M. and Kahle, K. (2014), “Declining propensity to play? A re-examination of the life-cycle theory”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 27, pp. 345-366.

Bertone, F., Colombo, M. and Croce, A., et al. (2013), “Corporate governance in high-tech firms”, The Oxford Handbook of Corporate Governance, in Wright et al., Oxford.

Bhattacharya, D., Chang, C. and Li, W. (2020), “Stages of firm life cycle, transition, and dividend policy”, Finance Research Letters, Vol. 33, p. 101226.

Black, B., Gledson de Carvalho, A. and Gorga, E. (2012), “What matters and for which firms for corporate governance in emerging markets? Evidence from Brazil (and other BRIK countries)”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 18, pp. 934-952.

Black, B., Jang, H. and Kim, W. (2006), “Predicting firms’ corporate governance choices. Evidence from Korea”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 12, pp. 660-691.

Claessens, S. and Yurtoglu, B. (2013), “Corporate governance in emerging markets: a survey”, Emerging Markets Review, Vol. 15, pp. 1-33.

DeAngelo, H., DeAngelo, L. and Stulz, R. (2006), “Dividend policy and the earned/contributed capital mix: a test of the lifecycle theory”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 81, pp. 227-254.

Dickinson, V. (2011), “Cash flow patterns as a proxy for firm lifecycle”, Accounting Review, Vol. 86, pp. 1969-1994.

Esqueda, O. and O’Connor, T. (2020), “Corporate governance and life cycles in emerging markets”, Research in International Business and Finance, Vol. 51, p. 101077.

Faff, R., Kwok, W., Podolski, E. and Wong, G. (2016), “Do corporate policies follow a lifecycle?”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 69, pp. 95-107.

Filatotchev, I., Toms, S. and Wright, M. (2006), “The firm’s strategic dynamics and corporate governance lifecycle”, International Journal of Managerial Finance, Vol. 2, pp. 256-279.

Gomes, A. (2000), “Going public without governance: managerial reputation effects”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 55, pp. 615-646.

Habib, A., Bhuiyan, M. and Hasan, M. (2018), “Firm life cycle and advisory directors”, Australian Journal of Management, Vol. 43, pp. 575-592.

Kieschnick, R. and Moussawi, R. (2018), “Firm age, corporate governance, and capital structure choices”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 48, pp. 597-614.

Kim, E. and Kim, W. (2008), “Changes in Korean corporate governance: a response to crisis”, Journal of Korean Law, Vol. 8, pp. 23-46.

Lee, W. and Choi, S. (2018), “Effects of corporate life cycle on corporate social responsibility: evidence from Korea”, Sustainability, Vol. 10, p. 3794.

Loderer, C., Stulz, R. and Waelchli, U. (2012), “Firm age and governance”, Working paper, University of Bern.

O’Connor, T. and Byrne, J. (2013), “Governance and the corporate lifecycle”, International Journal of Managerial Finance, Vol. 11, pp. 23-43.

Petersen, M. (2009), “Estimating standard errors in finance panel data sets: comparing approaches”, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 22, pp. 435-480.

Von Eije, H. and Megginson, W. (2008), “Dividends and share repurchases in the European Union”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 89, pp. 347-374.

Corresponding author

Thomas O’Connor can be contacted at: thomas.g.oconnor@mu.ie

About the authors

Bridget McNally is based at the School of Business, Maynooth University, Maynooth, Ireland

Thomas O’Connor is based at the School of Business, Maynooth University, Maynooth, Ireland

Related articles