The interest rate sensitivity of output and prices with different levels of financial inclusion: Evidence from developing economies

Huong Thi Truc Nguyen (University of Economics Ho Chi Minh City, Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam)

Journal of Economics and Development

ISSN: 1859-0020

Article publication date: 21 October 2019

Issue publication date: 13 December 2019

1328

Abstract

Purpose

The purpose of this paper is to evaluate the interest rate (IR) sensitivity of output and prices in developing economies with different levels of financial inclusion (FI) for the period 2007Q1–2017Q4.

Design/methodology/approach

By using the PCA method to construct an FI index for each country, the author divides the sample into two groups (high and low FI levels). Then, with panel vector autoregressions on per group estimated to assess the strength of the impulse response of output and prices to IR shock.

Findings

The findings show that the impact of an IR shock on output and inflation is greater in economies with a higher degree of FI.

Practical implications

The finding indicates the link between FI and the effectiveness of IRs as a monetary policy tool, thereby helping Central banks to have a clearer goal of FI to implement their monetary policy.

Originality/value

This study emphasizes the important role of FI in the economy. From there, an FI solution is integrated into the construction and calculation of its impact on monetary policy, improving the efficiency of monetary policy transmission, contributing to price stability and sustainable growth.

Keywords

Citation

Nguyen, H.T.T. (2019), "The interest rate sensitivity of output and prices with different levels of financial inclusion: Evidence from developing economies", Journal of Economics and Development, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 114-130. https://doi.org/10.1108/JED-07-2019-0018

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2019, Huong Thi Truc Nguyen

License

Published in Journal of Economics and Development. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

Financial inclusion (FI) delivered in a responsible and sustainable way has gained prominence in the policy agenda in developing countries over the past decade. Accordingly, the lack of access by a large percentage of population in these countries including Vietnam to formal financial services is a major policy concern. Because economic opportunities are linked to access to financial services, and that access particularly affects the poor as it allows them to save, invest and benefit from credit (Subbarao, 2009). From the efforts to get the majority of people access to formal financial services, it has contributed to increasing the overall efficiency of the economy and the financial system. However, such benefits are limited to developed economies, since most developing economies lack access to financial services (more than 90 percent of 1.7bn people in the world do not have an account at a financial institution – Demirguc-Kunt et al., 2018). Hence, FI is not only important but also the main goal of top priority in these countries.

On the other hand, most of the research on FI has focused on issues of measuring (e.g. Sarma, 2008; Demirguc-Kunt and Klapper, 2012; Park and Mercado, 2015; Camara and Tuesta, 2014; Mialou et al., 2017), poverty reduction and inclusive growth (Chibba, 2009; Park and Mercado, 2015; Okoye et al., 2017; Okere and Ozuzu, 2018) or financial stability (e.g. Hannig and Jansen, 2010; Khan, 2011; Han and Melecky, 2013; Morgan and Pontines, 2014; Garcia, 2016; Neaime and Gaysset, 2018). However, the level of access to financial services of all economic segments in society, especially services which allow for saving and borrowing at a market interest rate (IR), is potentially relevant for monetary policy and in particular the strength of the monetary transmission mechanism. Meanwhile, empirical research on this topic in developing countries is rather limited. Only a few studies such as Mehrotra and Yetman (2014, 2015) and Mehrotra and Nadhanael (2016) had attempted to investigate the link between the effectiveness of IRs as a policy tool and FI.

In addition, in Keynes’s standard neo-macroeconomic models, the transmission of monetary policy depends on private expenditures being interest elastic, so that a rise/fall in the policy IR induces a fall/rise in private expenditures, which in turn affects real output and inflation, because most standard neo-Keynesian macroeconomic models contain no explicit modeling of the financial system. Thus, implicitly, it is assumed that consumers have access to financial services at the going market IR for these services, i.e. they can borrow and save at market IRs (Berg et al., 2006; Clarida et al., 1999; Svensson, 2000). However, this is not possible in many developing countries, because most people are excluded from access to financial services and especially access to credit. Consumers cannot borrow to smooth their consumption in the face of an income shock. It can be seen that, in principle, this financial exclusion would reduce the IR elasticity of private spending and thus weaken the IR transmission of monetary policy. So, whether or not there is a change in the IR sensitivity of output and prices to the different levels of FI in developing countries. This is also the main research question of this article. From this, it can be seen that this study is necessary and worthwhile. Because, by answering this research question, we can find the link between the effectiveness of IRs as a monetary policy tool and FI, thereby helping policy makers, in particular Central bankers, have a clearer goal of FI to implement their monetary policy.

Based on the FI index built by the principal component analysis (PCA) method, we divide the sample into two FI groups: high and low degree of FI. By using panel vector auto-regression (PVAR), the study examines the impact on the output gap and inflation of a shock to IR in the two groups of economies with different levels of FI to answer the main research question.

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 provides an overview of the theoretical basis and associated empirical evidence. Section 3 discusses the data and methodology. Subsequently, we report our findings and discussion in Section 4. Finally, Section 5 provides conclusion and policy implications.

2. Literature review

2.1 Concept of financial inclusion

There is growing literature addressing the definition of FI. Despite the difference in the definition of this concept, it is generally acknowledged that FI is the process of ensuring that people have easy access to and use of financial services from the formal financial institutions in a timely, adequate, affordable manner, especially for the financial disadvantaged group (Sarma, 2008; De Koker and Jentzsch, 2013; Joshi et al., 2014). For the World Bank (2018), FI means as individuals and businesses have access to useful and affordable financial products and services that meet their needs (transactions; payments; savings; credit and insurance) delivered in a responsible and sustainable way.

Over the years, scholars as well as policy makers have made great efforts to measure FI. One of the first attempts to measure the financial sector’s access to nations was made by Beck et al. (2007). Accordingly, the authors have designed new indicators of bank access for three types of services including deposits, loans and payments through two dimensions of access and use of financial services. Demirguc-Kunt and Klapper (2012) and Demirguc-Kunt et al. (2015, 2018) have provided a set of indicators to measure the level of savings, borrowing, payment and risk management of adults in the world. However, FI is a multidimensional concept that cannot be accurately captured by individual indicators. Because, when used alone, these indicators can only provide partial and incomplete information about the comprehensiveness of the financial system. Even the use of individual indicators can lead to misunderstandings about the level of FI in an economy (Sarma, 2016). Thus, the measurement of FI of a country is realized by the FI index. Along with that, there are many methods to develop the FI index (e.g. Sarma, 2008, 2015, 2016; Demirguc-Kunt and Klapper, 2012). However, it assigns weights to all variables and dimensions based on the author’s experience, and assumes that all parameters have the same effect on FI. That is also the cause of criticism in the academic community. Therefore, the contribution of Amidžić et al. (2014) in providing an index using factor analysis (FA) or PCA method of Camara and Tuesta (2014) to determine the appropriate weights for calculating the FI index is an attempt to overcome the previous criticism, less arbitrary in proposing weights for variables and dimensions.

2.2 Theoretical and empirical literature

The common theoretical framework used to explain the monetary policy response to FI levels is the research model of Galí et al. (2004). In the model, the economy includes those who have access to financial markets and those who do not make savings or borrowings that consume their entire income. Accordingly, the resolution of parameter values under the Taylor rule shows that this greatly depends on the proportion of households that have access to financial markets. One major reason for the monetary policy outlook to become unstable when the level of FI falls is that financially excluded consumers are not directly affected by IRs, which makes monetary policy less effective (Mehrotra and Yetman, 2014). This shows the implications of limiting access to finance for the policy response function of the central bank and the effectiveness of monetary policy. Mehrotra and Yetman (2015) also argue that FI changes the behavior of businesses and consumers, which may affect the effectiveness of monetary policy. First, the increase in finance facilitates consumption, as households have easy access to tools for saving and borrowing. As a result, the output fluctuation is less costly, contributing to creating conditions for the central banks to maintain price stability. Second, enhancing FI may increase the importance of IRs in the transmission of monetary policy, enabling the central bank to improve the effectiveness of monetary policy. In asset market participation, Bilbiie and Straub (2012) also show how changes can lead to a change in the sign of the IR coefficient in the output Euler equation when asset market participation increases. Such considerations suggest that there could be important differences in the IR sensitivity of output and prices across economies, depending on the level of FI.

As mentioned in the introduction, the empirical literature on FI and monetary policy transmission in developing countries is rather limited. Several studies show that FI has a significant impact on monetary policy (e.g. Lapukeni, 2015; Lenka and Bairwa, 2016). However, these studies mainly focus on the impact of FI on monetary policy in the aspect of the central banks choosing to maintain and stabilize prices to implement monetary policy. Accordingly, inflation is used as a proxy for monetary policy. In contrast, Evans (2016) argues that although there is a one-way effect from monetary policy effectiveness to FI, there seems to be no impact in the opposite direction. However, the model used by the author lacks theoretical backing and therefore does not provide conclusive estimates of the relationship between FI and monetary policy.

Mehrotra and Yetman (2014) build on the Galí et al. (2004) model, in which financial excluded consumers are assumed to simply consume all their income each period, while included consumers have access to financial markets. From a policy perspective, the key difference between the two is that included consumers can smooth their consumption in response to shocks that hit the economy, while excluded consumers cannot. By using a PVAR, the authors found that the ratio of output volatility to inflation volatility increased in the share of financially included consumers in the economy when monetary policy was conducted optimally. On the other hand, Mehrotra and Nadhanael (2016) evaluate the IR sensitivity of output and prices in emerging Asian economies with different levels of FI. This is done both by estimating output Euler equations (similar in spirit to Bilbiie and Straub, 2012) and examining the impact of IR shocks on output and prices in PVAR. From estimates of the real IR coefficient in output Euler equations and from vector autoregressions that consider impacts of nominal IR shocks on output and prices, they find that the IR sensitivity of output and prices is higher in economies with a greater degree of FI.

However, except for Mehrotra and Nadhanael (2016), none of these have investigated whether the IR sensitivity of output and prices changes for the degree of FI in developing economies. We therefore aim to address this gap in the literature. Our approach is similar in spirit to Bilbiie and Straub (2012) and Mehrotra and Nadhanael (2016). However, instead of using only the World Bank’s indicator of account ownership in 2011 as the method of Mehrotra and Nadhanael (2016), we divided the sample into two separate groups (high and low FI levels) by using PCA to construct a composite FI index for each economy.

3. Methodology

3.1 Data

This study uses annual data collected from the results of financial access survey to calculate the FI index and quarterly data from international financial statistics of the International Monetary Fund for period 2007Q1–2017Q4 to analyze the impact of an IR shock on output and inflation in 21 developing countries (the list is attached in Appendix). Our research sample does not cover all developing countries because countries data are incomplete over the years. The starting year of the research period is 2007 because after the global financial crisis 2007–2008, the policy makers around the world re-recognize and determine that a need to focus on FI direction in a sustainable way can achieve financial stability and comprehensive growth (Garcia, 2016).

3.2 Research models and measurement variables

3.2.1 Financial inclusion index (FI index)

As mentioned in the literature review, there are two parametric analyses commonly used for indexing: FA and PCA. However, PCA is preferred over FA as an indexing strategy because it is not necessary to make assumptions on the raw data, such as selecting the underlying number of common factors (Camara and Tuesta, 2014 cited in Steiger, 1979). Therefore, we develop an FI index via the PCA method. Because it is imperative that measures of FI reflect the multidimensional nature of FI.

In computing our FI index, we combine the approaches of Sarma (2008, 2015, 2016) and Camara and Tuesta (2014). Like Sarma, we use: access, availability and usage as dimensions of our FI index. And based on Camara and Tuesta (2014), we develop a composite FI index via PCA method which is displayed in the form of:

(1) FII i j = w i j X i ,
where FIIij is the FI index, wij is the weight on factor score coefficient and Xi is the respective original value of the components.

The variables in the model are as follows:

  • Access (banking penetration): the number of deposit bank accounts per 1,000 adult population.

  • Availability (availability of banking services): number of commercial bank branches per 100,000 adults, and number of ATMs per 100,000 adults.

  • Usage: as proposed by Beck et al. (2007), Gupte et al. (2012), Lenka and Bairwa (2016) and Sarma (2016), we consider two basic services of the banking system to be credit and deposit. Accordingly, outstanding loans from commercial banks (% of GDP) and outstanding deposits with commercial banks (% of GDP) are used to measure this dimension.

By the PCA method, FII is constructed by combining these three dimensions and five elements.

3.2.2 The impact of an interest rate shock on output and inflation

Based on suggestions from Mehrotra and Nadhanael (2016), our approach is similar in spirit to Bilbiie and Straub (2012) from the Euler equations are based on hybrid models, we estimate PVAR models using the methodology proposed by Love and Zicchino (2006), with the vector of endogenous variables set as [y, ir, π]. In reduced form, PVAR frameworks are shown as follows:

(2) Y i , t = α i + Г ( L ) Y i , t + ε i , t ,
where Yi,t is a vector of endogenous variables: output gap (y) – the difference between actual GDP and potential GDP; interest rate (ir); inflation (π); Yit=(yt,i, iri,t, πi,t)’; αi is a vector of constants; Г(L) is a matrix polynomial in the lag operator; εi,t is a vector of error terms.

3.3 Methodology

3.3.1 Calculate a composite FI index

To divide the sample into two separate FI groups (high and low degrees of FI), we build the composite FI index for developing economies by employing the PCA method from Equation (1). If the economy has an average of the FI index >0.5, then classify it into a group of high FI level and vice versa (i.e. average of the FI index ⩽ 0.5: low FI level).

3.3.2 Analyze the impact of an interest rate shock on output and inflation

Focusing again on two groups of economies that have been divided above, we estimate PVAR models (2) using the methodology proposed by Love and Zicchino (2006). After estimating the above reduced-form models, shocks are identified by the conventional Cholesky decomposition of the variance-covariance matrix. Then, we examine the magnitude of a one standard deviation shock to the IR and the impact of changes in IRs on output and prices in the two groups of economies. In addition, the output gap is based on data for real GDP, with the cycle extracted by means of a Hodrick–Prescott filter (supported from Stata software).

4. Results and discussion

4.1 FI index

Before using PCA, indicators of each dimension are normalized to have values between 0 and 1 to ensure that the scale in which they are measured is immaterial. Through the PCA method, we calculated eigenvalues of the all five factors (described in Table I). The highest eigenvalue of the components retains more standardized variance among others, and an eigenvalue greater than 1 is considered for the analysis (Kaiser, 1960). According to Lenka and Bairwa (2016), if the value contains more than one component, then we may consider more than one principal component (PC) in the financial analysis. Then, taking the weight of each factor (calculated by PCA) multiply it by the corresponding variable and add them to get the final index.

Table AII shows the results of the PCA. We can see the eigenvalues of the five PCs are 2.28, 1.35, 0.79, 0.35 and 0.23. This shows that there are two PCs have eigenvalue greater than 1, so we take the first two components and continue using PCA (Table AIV) to find the weights assigned to the PCs. After performing the KMO test (Tables AIII and AV) to examine the suitability of the factors and by doing so we get the composite FI index for developing countries as shown in Tables II and III.

From the above results, we divided the sample into two separate groups. The first group consists of countries with an average value of FI index>0.5, known as a high FI level group (see Table II). The second group is a low FI level group (the remaining countries with the average value of FI index ⩽ 0.5 – see Table III).

4.2 Sensitivity analysis

On the basis of unit-root test results using Fisher-type unit-root test based on augmented Dickey–Fuller in Table IV, where all the three series (Panels A, B and C) are stationary at the 1 percent significance level, since the p-values are all smaller than 0.01. This means there are no unit roots in our panels under the given test conditions.

The choice of the lag length was determined as the minimum number of lags that merits the crucial assumption of time independence of the residuals. The results for the panel VAR lag order selection are shown in Table V.

Based on the three model selection criteria by Andrews and Lu (2001), second-order panel VAR is the preferred model, since this has the smallest MAIC (−8.47) and MQIC (−84.3). In addition, according to these authors, for the smallest sample size, MAIC is the best of the three procedures. Thus, the underlying PVAR model is estimated using two lags.

After we estimate GMM by using GMM estimation implemented by PVAR (Table AVI) and then test for Granger causality (Table AVII), we can find IR, Granger-cause inflation (INF) and output gap (Ygap). This means changes in INF and Y gap have cause on the changes in IR.

The results from Table VI show that the moduli of the companion matrix based on the estimated parameters are all smaller than 1 (proposed by Hamilton, 1995; Lütkepohl, 2005). We conclude that the model is stable.

See Figure 1, we can also see that the model is stable because the roots of the companion matrix are all inside the unit circle.

Based on the forecast error variance decomposition (FEVD) estimates from Table VII, we see that in high FI level group, nearly 2.7 percent of the variation in output gap and 6.3 percent of the variation in inflation can be explained by the shock of IRs. On the other hand, these rates in low FI level group are only 0.1 and 4.4 percent, respectively. This shows that the impact of changes in IRs on output and prices is much larger in countries with high FI level than it is in countries with a low FI level.

In our model, actually, estimates made for impulse response function (IRF) are the core of the research, because we are trying to understand what happens with output and prices, when a shock in the IR occurs. In order to obtain the needed results, we need to focus on the response of IR on the change of 1 standard deviation from itself and from output gap and inflation. The estimate results for IRF are shown in Table VIII.

The second column of Table VIII shows the magnitude of a one standard deviation shock to the IR in the two groups of economies. We see that short-term IRs are much more volatile in economies with a higher degree of FI (1.025 > 0.56). And the next two columns focus on the impact of IR shocks of one percentage point on the output gap and inflation. The estimates also suggest that the impact of an IR shock on output and inflation is larger in economies with a higher degree of FI. In particular, in the model with two lags, the point impact on output is around 3.5 times as large (i.e. 0.0125 compared to 0.0036 – see the third column in Table VIII), and the impact on inflation approximately 2.4 times as big in these economies (i.e. 1.0024 compared to 0.4216 – see the last column in Table VIII), compared to those with less financial access. These results are in line with the findings of Mehrotra and Nadhanael (2016) and Mehrotra and Yetman (2014), where the ratio of output volatility to inflation volatility was found to increase with the share of financially included consumers in the economy.

Figure 2, graphs of the IRFs and the 5 percent error bands generated by Monte Carlo simulation, reports graphs of impulse responses for the model with three variables estimated for a sample of countries with low FI level (on the left), and countries with high FI (on the right). The black line represents the IRF and the gray band is the 95 percent confidence interval for the IRF.

Specifically, the bottom row of the graphs shows the impact of IR shock on output (IR: Ygap) and prices (IR: INF) in two groups (low and high FI levels). For high FI group, the initial impact of a structural one standard deviation shock to IR on inflation (prices) is 0.5033 (50.33 percent) and rises to a maximum of 1.1214 (112.14 percent) in the fourth quarter, thereafter it begins to dissipate. On the other hand, it is only 0.1776 (17.76 percent) for low FI group, rising to 0.4428 (44.28 percent) in the third quarter, before dissipating thereafter (data are in Table AVIII). It shows that the effect of an IR shock on prices (inflation) is greater than in economies with higher FI level. Similarly, the graph (IR: Ygap) also displays that the response of output volatility to IR shock is more pronounced for economies with a higher level of FI.

Consistent with the FEVD results (as mentioned in Table VII), the study indicates that the IR sensitivity of output and prices is larger for high FI group which suggests that economies with a higher degree of FI have stronger the IR sensitivity of output and prices than economies with a lower degree of FI.

Overall, our findings have yielded results consistent with other scholars’ studies (e.g. Mehrotra and Nadhanael, 2016; Mehrotra and Yetman, 2014). This is also in line with the theoretical model results of Bilbiie and Straub (2012), where changes in asset market participation can lead to a change in the sign of the IR coefficient in the output Euler equation when asset market participation increases. Approach research in this spirit, Mehrotra and Nadhanael (2016) also argued that the FI level is directly related to monetary policy. The most obvious channel is through the importance of IRs in the economy. Accordingly, economies with higher FI levels tend to exhibit the higher IR sensitivity of output and prices. This increases the importance of the IR channel in the transmission of monetary policy.

5. Conclusion and policy implications

This paper uses a PVAR approach to analyze the IR sensitivity of output and prices with different levels of FI in developing economies over the 2007Q1–2017Q4 period. The results show that short-term IRs are much more volatile in economies with a higher degree of FI. Similar to the magnitude of a one standard deviation shock to the IR, the impact of an IR shock on output and inflation is larger in economies with a higher degree of FI. Accordingly, this paper also indicates the link between the effectiveness of IRs as a monetary policy tool and FI. In other words, the effectiveness of monetary policy depends on the levels of FI in the economy, because a higher level of FI may facilitate increased participation of different sectors of the economy in the formal financial system. And as the proportion of the formal financial sector increases, it increases the effectiveness of IRs as an important policy tool for macroeconomic stability (Cecchetti and Kharroubi, 2012). Monetary policy operates primarily through its influence on the financial system. Therefore, any development affecting the structure or condition of the financial system will likely affect the transmission mechanism of monetary policy (Ma and Lin, 2016). So, the efforts of governments in developing economies should not only be on the behavior of macroeconomic variables to influence their monetary policy but also on FI.

It is clear that FI brings many economic benefits to individuals, small businesses and sustainable growth in general. It facilitates the attainment of macroeconomic goals including output growth, poverty reduction, bridging of income inequality and price stability (Beck et al., 2007). However, its impact on monetary policy in general and the effectiveness of monetary policy transmission in particular are rarely mentioned. Thus, this study contributes to the advancement of the theory of the relationship between FI and monetary policy through IR tool. It also helps policy makers, the Central bank and communities see such importance of FI in the economy. From there, an FI solution is integrated into the construction and calculation of its impact on monetary policy, improving the efficiency of monetary policy transmission, contributing to price stability and sustainable growth.

For developing countries, the importance of FI for these countries has become much more evident in recent years. Many countries also have made a commitment to place a priority on FI. However, these economies are still largely based on cash transactions. A large portion of the adults has not yet used formal financial services. Therefore, the transition to a non-cash system needs to be prioritized in order to improve efficiency and promote economic development. In addition, one of the focal points that the governments of these countries need to toward is the strengthening of access to and use of financial services for the people. And the task of policy makers is to focus on innovation, diversifying financial services, improving financial infrastructure and accelerating the use of digital technology in the economy. In particular, focus on promoting the adoption of mobile money technology and increasing utilization of microfinance service initiatives. In addition, owning an account is an important first step toward FI. But to fully benefit from having an account, people need to be able to use it in safe and convenient ways. Thus, financial service providers need to offer safe, affordable and convenient products that make using accounts more appealing than using cash.

For policy outcomes in terms of output and inflation, in developing countries, most Central banks use Keynes’s new standard macroeconomic models for policy analysis. Accordingly, the transmission mechanism of monetary policy largely depends on private investment as IR elasticity. Thus, an increase in the monetary policy IR induces a decrease in private investment and vice versa. Finally, real output and inflation are affected. So, if there are a large share of financially excluded households in an economy, the IR elasticity of private consumption will be reduced. This is because financially inclusive households are able to absorb shocks, and thus can consume more smoothly than financially excluded households.

From a policy perspective, therefore, monetary authorities in developing countries need to focus more on output growth than inflation. This could support income stabilization, allowing finely excluded households to consume smoothly. At the same time, it is necessary to enhance FI in the economy so that monetary policy can more fully achieve its objectives.

Figures

Graph of eigenvalue stability condition

Figure 1

Graph of eigenvalue stability condition

Graphs of impulse responses functions

Figure 2

Graphs of impulse responses functions

Summary of variables and data sources are used to build FI index

Dimension/Variable Description Data sources
Access (penetration)
Accounts Deposit accounts with commercial banks per 1,000 adults FAS – IMF
Availability
Branch banks Branches of commercial banks per 100,000 adults FAS – IMF
ATMs Automated Teller Machines (ATMs) per 100,000 adults
Usage
Deposits Outstanding deposits with commercial banks (% of GDP) FAS – IMF
Loans Outstanding loans with commercial banks (% of GDP)

Source: The authors

Estimation of the FI index of high FI level group in developing countries

FI index
Year Bulgaria Chile Macedonia Malaysia Mauritius South Africa Thailand Ukraine Vietnam
2007 0.84 0.55 0.35 0.81 0.77 0.39 0.53 0.76 0.39
2008 0.94 0.64 0.49 0.80 0.81 0.45 0.61 0.89 0.38
2009 0.98 0.64 0.54 0.93 0.85 0.48 0.63 0.91 0.50
2010 0.99 0.65 0.56 0.91 0.92 0.48 0.64 0.91 0.58
2011 0.91 0.70 0.56 0.94 0.91 0.49 0.68 0.91 0.54
2012 0.92 0.74 0.59 0.96 0.93 0.53 0.75 0.98 0.53
2013 0.93 0.75 0.60 1.00 0.93 0.55 0.80 0.83 0.58
2014 0.89 0.75 0.63 0.98 0.95 0.59 0.83 0.81 0.62
2015 0.87 0.77 0.66 0.97 0.99 0.60 0.85 0.70 0.70
2016 0.83 0.78 0.65 0.94 0.94 0.60 0.84 0.67 0.79
2017 0.83 0.78 0.65 0.90 0.93 0.60 0.85 0.68 0.83
Mean 0.91 0.71 0.57 0.92 0.90 0.52 0.73 0.82 0.59

Source: Calculated by the authors using PCA method on Stata 14

Estimation of the FI index of low FI level group in developing countries

FI index
Year Algeria Armenia Bolivia Costa Rica Guatemala Hungary India Indonesia Jamaica Mexico Peru The Philippines
2007 0.12 0.03 0.00 0.38 0.23 0.40 0.20 0.10 0.20 0.14 0.07 0.05
2008 0.12 0.08 0.00 0.41 0.25 0.45 0.24 0.11 0.20 0.20 0.13 0.07
2009 0.12 0.15 0.06 0.42 0.27 0.46 0.27 0.12 0.20 0.21 0.14 0.08
2010 0.11 0.18 0.07 0.41 0.29 0.46 0.28 0.12 0.19 0.24 0.17 0.09
2011 0.10 0.27 0.10 0.45 0.31 0.47 0.30 0.17 0.18 0.21 0.20 0.11
2012 0.11 0.33 0.12 0.47 0.34 0.43 0.33 0.26 0.20 0.23 0.23 0.12
2013 0.13 0.38 0.15 0.54 0.38 0.41 0.36 0.32 0.21 0.27 0.27 0.16
2014 0.18 0.45 0.19 0.58 0.40 0.40 0.41 0.35 0.22 0.24 0.34 0.17
2015 0.20 0.46 0.24 0.54 0.41 0.37 0.44 0.37 0.23 0.26 0.57 0.19
2016 0.20 0.50 0.27 0.58 0.40 0.37 0.46 0.39 0.25 0.28 0.55 0.22
2017 0.21 0.52 0.30 0.60 0.38 0.38 0.48 0.45 0.33 0.27 0.54 0.24
Mean 0.15 0.30 0.14 0.49 0.33 0.42 0.34 0.25 0.22 0.23 0.29 0.14

Source: Calculated by the authors using PCA method on Stata 14

Panel unit-root test

Statistic p-value
Panel A: Fisher-type unit-root test for IR (based on augmented Dickey–Fuller tests)
Inverse χ2 (42) P 141.1263 0.0000
Inverse normal Z −3.7963 0.0001
Inverse logit t (104) L* −6.7283 0.0000
Modified inv. χ2 Pm 10.8156 0.0000
Panel B: Fisher-type unit-root test for INF (based on augmented Dickey–Fuller tests)
Inverse χ2 (42) P 190.8418 0.0000
Inverse normal Z −9.7501 0.0000
Inverse logit t (109) L* −11.3288 0.0000
Modified inv. χ2 Pm 16.2400 0.0000
Panel C: Fisher-type unit-root test for Ygap (based on augmented Dickey–Fuller tests)
Inverse χ2 (42) P 432.5446 0.0000
Inverse normal Z −15.0169 0.0000
Inverse logit t (104) L* −26.0654 0.0000
Modified inv. χ2 Pm 42.6119 0.0000

Note: For the two statistics Z and L*; if the realization is lower than the normal law level (−1.64 at the 5 percent significance level), rejects the null hypothesis

Source: Calculated by the authors using unit-root test on Stata 14

The result of lag length selection criteria

lag CD J J p-value MBIC MAIC MQIC
1 0.999995 138.0161 1.1490848 −203.3547 24.01606 −66.0346
2 1 87.52919 0.0004277 −199.941 −8.470812 −84.30294
3 1 82.00171 0.0001017 −157.5567 2.001713 −61.19173

Source: Calculated by the authors using PVAR on Stata 14

Eigenvalue stability condition

Low FI level group High FI level group
Eigenvalue Eigenvalue
Real Imaginary Modulus Real Imaginary Modulus
0.9986204 0 0.9986204 0.9554152 0.0381895 0.9561781
0.874434 −0.0241578 0.8747676 0.9554152 −0.0381895 0.9561781
0.874434 0.0241578 0.8747676 0.9043196 0 0.9043196
0.5811525 −0.3611747 0.6842408 0.7165484 −0.2688763 0.7653339
0.5811525 0.3611747 0.6842408 0.7165484 0.2688763 0.7653339
0.1548274 0 0.1548274 0.0650641 0 0.0650641

Source: Calculated by the authors using PVAR on Stata 14

Variance decomposition

Low FI level group High FI level group
Impulse variable Impulse variable
Response variable IR INF Ygap IR INF Ygap
IR 0.9985 0.0014 0.00001 0.98593 0.0139 0.00007
INF 0.0440 0.9559 0.00004 0.06319 0.9368 0.86106
Ygap 0.0010 0.0106 0.98842 0.02665 0.0249 0.94843

Source: Calculated by the authors using PVAR on Stata 14

Impact of shocks to interest rate

One standard deviation shock to interest rate Response to 1% point shock in interest rate
(IR) Output gap Inflation
Low FI level group 0.5596 0.0036 0.4216
High FI level group 1.0254 −0.0125 1.0024

List of countries

Algeria Hungary Mexico
Republic of Armenia India Peru
Bolivia Indonesia The Philippines
Bulgaria Jamaica South Africa
Chile Macedonia, FYR Thailand
Costa Rica Malaysia Ukraine
Guatemala Mauritius Vietnam

Principal components/correlation (five factors)

Component Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative
Comp1 2.2805 0.932842 0.4561 0.4561
Comp2 1.34766 0.553287 0.2695 0.7256
Comp3 0.794372 0.443765 0.1589 0.8845
Comp4 0.350607 0.123747 0.0701 0.9546
Comp5 0.22686 0 0.0454 1.0000
Principal components (eigenvectors)
Variable Comp1 Comp2 Unexplained
zaccount 0.5323 0.1955 0.3024
zATM 0.4490 0.4877 0.2196
zBank 0.2302 0.5070 0.5328
zDepst 0.4129 −0.5676 0.1771
zloan 0.5400 −0.3805 0.14

Kaiser–Meyer–Olkin test (five factors)

Variable KMO
zaccount 0.6860
zATM 0.5302
zBank 0.5643
zDepst 0.4815
zloan 0.5668
Overall 0.5630

Principal components/correlation (two factors) (to find out weights)

Component Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative
Comp1 1.25711 0.514221 0.6286 0.6286
Comp2 0.74289 0 0.3714 1.0000
Principal components (eigenvectors)
Variable Comp1 Unexplained
zFII1 0.7071 0.3714
zFII2 0.7071 0.3714

Kaiser–Meyer–Olkin test (two factors)

Variable KMO
zFII1 0.5000
zFII2 0.5000
Overall 0.5000

GMM estimation

Variable Low FI level group High FI level group
IR
IR
 L1. 1.049*** 1.006***
 L2. −0.140*** −0.044
INF
 L1. 0.028 0.081***
 L2. −0.004 −0.108***
Ygap
 L1. −0.196 0.557
 L2. 0.215 −0.552
INF
IR
 L1. 0.214** 0.094
 L2. −0.025 0.070
INF
 L1. 1.185*** 1.412***
 L2. −0.481*** −0.598***
Ygap
 L1. −0.693 0.492
 L2. 0.654 −0.536
Ygap
IR
 L1. 0.000 −0.003*
 L2. 0.004* 0.003**
INF
 L1. −0.001 −0.001
 L2. 0.000 0.002***
Ygap
 L1. 1.831*** 1.896***
 L2. −0.832*** −0.900***

Notes: *p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01

Panel VAR-Granger causality Wald test

Low FI level group High FI level group
Equation\Excluded χ2 df Prob>χ2 χ2 df Prob>χ2
IR
INF 3.216 2 0.200 68.340 2 0.000
Ygap 0.636 2 0.728 2.807 2 0.246
All 4.874 4 0.300 92.787 4 0.000
INF
IR 13.031 2 0.001 5.165 2 0.076
Ygap 1.107 2 0.575 2.026 2 0.363
All 15.193 4 0.004 5.315 4 0.256
Ygap
IR 25.068 2 0.000 4.368 2 0.113
INF 1.033 2 0.597 42.045 2 0.000
All 32.560 4 0.000 93.625 4 0.000

Orthogonalized IRF

Low FI level group High FI level group
Impulse variable Impulse variable
Response variable and forecast horizon INF IR Ygap INF IR Ygap
INF
 0 1.13197 0.17763 0 2.11024 0.50331 0
 1 1.34013 0.33180 −0.01205 2.98177 0.80421 0.01107
 2 1.04976 0.42163 −0.02572 2.96665 1.00242 0.02572
 3 0.61263 0.44280 −0.03554 2.43872 1.10334 0.03981
 4 0.23853 0.41444 −0.04006 1.69672 1.12140 0.05099
 5 0.00655 0.36154 −0.04016 0.94783 1.07832 0.05827
 6 −0.0895 0.30423 −0.03755 0.31393 0.99693 0.06161
 7 −0.0942 0.25414 −0.03385 −0.15162 0.89720 0.06154
 8 −0.0559 0.21531 −0.03014 −0.44372 0.79428 0.05889
 9 −0.0104 0.18692 −0.02694 −0.58622 0.69815 0.05449
10 0.02327 0.16608 −0.02435 −0.61628 0.61417 0.04911
Ygap
 0 0.00209 0.00050 0.01738 0.00413 −0.00240 0.02253
 1 0.00311 0.00104 0.03182 0.00664 −0.00772 0.04271
 2 0.00320 0.00359 0.04380 0.01013 −0.01246 0.06065
 3 0.00286 0.00787 0.05372 0.01632 −0.0160 0.07651
 4 0.00254 0.01341 0.06191 0.01632 −0.0160 0.07651
 5 0.00252 0.01982 0.06863 0.03696 −0.01920 0.10266
 6 0.00292 0.02682 0.07413 0.04974 −0.01869 0.11325
 7 0.00367 0.03416 0.07860 0.06272 −0.01694 0.12236
 8 0.00467 0.04166 0.08220 0.07498 −0.01417 0.13012
 9 0.00581 0.04916 0.08508 0.08587 −0.01058 0.13663
10 0.00701 0.05655 0.08735 0.09502 −0.00639 0.14200

References

Amidžić, G., Massara, M.A. and Mialou, A. (2014), “Assessing countries' financial inclusion standing-a new composite index (No. 14-36)”, International Monetary Fund.

Andrews, D.W.K. and Lu, B. (2001), “Consistent model and moment selection procedures for GMM estimation with application to dynamic panel data models”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 101 No. 1, pp. 123-164.

Beck, T., Demirguc-Kunt, A. and Peria, M.S.M. (2007), “Reaching out: access to and use of banking services across countries”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 85 No. 1, pp. 234-266.

Berg, A., Karam, P. and Laxton, D. (2006), “A practrocal model based approach to monetay policy analysis-overview”, Working Paper No. WP/06/80, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, available at: www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2006/wp0680.pdf

Bilbiie, F.O. and Straub, R. (2012), “Changes in the output Euler equation and asset markets participation”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 36 No. 11, pp. 1659-1672.

Camara, N. and Tuesta, D. (2014), “Measuring financial inclusion: a multidimensional index”, No. 1426, BBVA Bank, Economic Research Department, Madrid, available at: www.bbvaresearch.com/wp-content/uploads/2014/09/WP14-26_Financial-Inclusion.pdf

Cecchetti, S. and Kharroubi, E. (2012), “Reassessing the impact of finance on growth”, BIS Working Paper No. 381, BIS, Basel.

Chibba, M. (2009), “Financial inclusion, poverty reduction and the millennium development goals”, The European Journal of Development Research, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 213-230.

Clarida, R., Gali, J. and Gertler, M. (1999), “The science of monetary policy: a new Keynesian perspective”, Journal of economic literature, Vol. 37 No. 4, pp. 1661-1707.

De Koker, L. and Jentzsch, N. (2013), “Financial inclusion and financial integrity: aligned incentives?”, World Development, Vol. 44, pp. 267-280.

Demirguc-Kunt, A. and Klapper, L. (2012), Measuring Financial Inclusion: The Global Findex Database, No. 6025, The World Bank, Washington, DC, available at: https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/6042/WPS6025.pdf?sequenc

Demirguc-Kunt, A., Klapper, L., Singer, D., Ansar, S. and Hess., J. (2018), The Global Findex Database 2017: Measuring Financial Inclusion and the Fintech Revolution, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Evans, O. (2016), “The effectiveness of monetary policy in Africa: modeling the impact of financial inclusion”, Iranian Economic Review, Vol. 20 No. 3, pp. 327-337.

Galí, J., López-Salido, J.D. and Vallés, J. (2004), “Rule-of-thumb consumers and the design of interest rate rules”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 36 No. 4, pp. 739-763.

Garcia, M.J. (2016), “Can financial inclusion and financial stability go hand in hand?”, Economic Issues Journal Articles, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 81-103.

Gupte, R., Venkataramani, B. and Gupta, D. (2012), “Computation of financial inclusion index for India”, Procedia – Social and Behavioral Sciences, Vol. 37, pp. 133-149.

Hamilton, J.D. (1995), “Time series analysis”, Economic Theory, Vol. II, Imprint, Princeton, NJ; Princeton University Press, Chichester, Mercer, NJ, pp. 625-630.

Han, R. and Melecky, M. (2013), Financial Inclusion for Financial Stability: Access to Bank Deposits and the Growth of Deposits in the Global Financial Crisis, No. 6577, The World Bank, Washington, DC.

Hannig, A. and Jansen, S. (2010), “Financial inclusion and financial stability: current policy issues”, ADBI Working Paper No. 259, Asian Development Bank Institute, Tokyo.

Joshi, V.K., Singh, M.R. and Jain, S. (2014), “Financial inclusion for sustainable development through Pradhan Mantri Jan-Dhan Yojana”, Professional Panorama: An International Journal of Applied Management & Technology, available at: www.professionalpanorama.in/wp-content/uploads/2015/02/14sonal-ji.pdf

Kaiser, H.F. (1960), “The application of electronic computers to factor analysis”, Educational and Psychological Measurement, Vol. 20 No. 1, pp. 141-151.

Khan, H.R. (2011), “Financial inclusion and financial stability: are they two sides of the same coin? Address by Shri HR Khan, Deputy Governor of the Reserve Bank of India, at BANCON 2011”, organized by the Indian Bankers Association and Indian Overseas Bank, Chennai, November 4.

Lapukeni, A.F. (2015), “The impact of financial inclusion on monetary policy effectiveness: the case of Malawi”, International Journal of Monetary Economics and Finance, Vol. 8 No. 4, pp. 360-384.

Lenka, S.K. and Bairwa, A.K. (2016), “Does financial inclusion affect monetary policy in SAARC countries?”, Cogent Economics & Finance, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 1-8.

Love, I. and Zicchino, L. (2006), “Financial development and dynamic investment behaviour: evidence from panel VAR”, Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 46 No. 2, pp. 190-210.

Lütkepohl, H. (2005), New Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis, Springer Science & Business Media, Florence City.

Ma, Y. and Lin, X. (2016), “Financial development and the effectiveness of monetary policy”, Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 68, pp. 1-11.

Mehrotra, A. and Nadhanael, G.V. (2016), “Financial inclusion and monetary policy in emerging Asia”, in Gopalan, S. and Kikuchi, T. (Eds), Financial Inclusion in Asia. Issues and Policy Concerns, Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp. 93-127.

Mehrotra, A. and Yetman, J. (2014), “Financial inclusion and optimal monetary policy”, BIS Working Paper No. 476, BIS, Basel.

Mehrotra, A.N. and Yetman, J. (2015), “Financial inclusion – issues for central banks”, BIS Quarterly Review, March.

Mialou, A., Amidzic, G. and Massara, A. (2017), “Assessing countries’ financial inclusion standing – a new composite index”, Journal of Banking and Financial Economics, Vol. 2 No. 8, pp. 105-126.

Morgan, P. and Pontines, V. (2014), Financial Stability and Financial Inclusion, No. 488, Asian Development Bank Institute, Tokyo.

Neaime, S. and Gaysset, I. (2018), “Financial inclusion and stability in MENA: evidence from poverty and inequality”, Finance Research Letters, Vol. 24, pp. 230-237.

Okere, P.A. and Ozuzu, P.N. (2018), “Financial inclusion and economic growth of Nigeria (the microfinance option)”, International Journal for Innovation Education and Research, Vol. 6 No. 2, pp. 61-74.

Okoye, L.U., Erin, O. and Modebe, N.J. (2017), “Financial inclusion as a strategy for enhanced economic growth and development”, The Journal of Internet Banking and Commerce, Vol. 22 No. S8, pp. 1-14.

Park, C.Y. and Mercado, R. (2015), Financial Inclusion, Poverty, and Income Inequality in Developing Asia, No. 426, Asian Development Bank, Metro Manila.

Sarma, M. (2008), “Index of financial inclusion”, Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations Working Paper No. 215, New Delhi.

Sarma, M. (2015), “Measuring financial inclusion”, Economics Bulletin, Vol. 35 No. 1, pp. 604-611.

Sarma, M. (2016), “Measuring financial inclusion for Asian economies”, in Gopalan, S. and Kikuchi, T. (Eds), Financial Inclusion in Asia. Issues and Policy Concerns, Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp. 3-34.

Steiger, J.H. (1979), “Factor indeterminacy in the 1930's and the 1970's some interesting parallels”, Psychometrika, Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 157-167.

Subbarao, D. (2009), “Financial inclusion: challenges and opportunities. Address Delivered at the Bankers Club, Kolkata, December 9.

Svensson, L.E. (2000), “Open-economy inflation targeting”, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 50 No. 1, pp. 155-183.

World Bank (2018), “Financial inclusion – overview”, available at: www.worldbank.org/en/topic/financialinclusion/overview (accessed June 30, 2019)

Corresponding author

Huong Thi Truc Nguyen can be contacted at: huongnttncskt2016@gmail.com

Related articles